Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management, Volume 6, Issue 3, 2011
The institutional determinants of CEO compensation:
An international empirical evidence
Habib Jouber
Lartige, Faculty of Economic, Sciences & Management, University of Sfax
Airport Road, P.O Box 1088, Sfax 3018, Tunisia
Telephone: +216 96672732
Email: habib.jouber@yahoo.com
Hamadi Fakhfakh
Lartige, Faculty of Economic, Sciences & Management, University of Sfax
Airport Road, P.O Box 1088, Sfax 3018, Tunisia
Telephone: +216 98657007
Email: hamadi.fakhfakh@fsegs.rnu.tn
Abstract
Corporate governance literature suggests that the relationship between CEO effort and outcomes such as firm
performance is highly uncertain due to the influence of numerous organizational and environmental
contingencies that are outside CEOs’ control. The major focus of this study is to determine whether institutional
factors explain cross-sectional differences in CEO pay structure and sensitivity to performance and luck. Thus,
we address three ultimate questions; Are CEOs rewarded for luck? Does institutional features matter for CEO
pay for luck? How do systematic incentive effect is sensitive to luck’s nature? Ordinary Least Squares (OLS)
and Instrumental Variables (I.V.) estimations based on a sample of 300 publicly traded firms covering four
countries from the Anglo-American and Euro-Continental corporate governance models between 2004 and 2008
show that the answers to the two first questions are a surrounding yes. Robustness check tests relying to the
third question provide evidence that pay for luck is asymmetric. That is, executives are rewarded for good luck
but they are safe of bad luck.
Keywords: CEO compensation, performance, institutional factors, luck, corporate governance
Acknowledgement: The authors would like to thank the associate editor and two anonymous reviewers for their
in-depth and insightful comments that shaped the paper. The authors also appreciate research assistance from
LARTIGE laboratory members
Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management / Business-and-Management.org
44
1 INTRODUCTION
At the heart of the issue of the managerial compensation’s impact on shareholder value is the conflict of
interests between corporate shareholders and managers. The assumption is that compensation contracts may
resolve or alleviate these conflicts (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). Existing research on this issue is based
primarily on the optimal contracting theory. Under this theory, CEO performance-based compensation helps
tying the CEO’s personal wealth to his firm’s stock price and, hence casting doubts on the possibilities that
CEOs take self-serving actions to harm shareholders. That is, management rewards should motivate executives
to take real actions that increase firm value. This view asserts however, that executives are rewarded only for
firm-specific performance’s improvements and that executive pay is the outcome of market mechanisms. Or, it
is commonly known that contractible performance measures capture the interaction between both specific and
systematic incentives (Holmstrom, 1979). With this in mind, one could rationalize this evidence in terms of the
principal’s disability to draw conclusions about the level of skills or effort the agent exerted. Such disability
occurs because a real portion of firm performance may be due to something over which executives have no
control, such as, for example macroeconomic trends or input and output price movements (Feriozzi, 2011).
Thus, a serious problem facing a shareholder is to determine how much of the firm performance is due to luck
and how much is due to skill. This is in fact the crux of Bertrand and Mullainathan’s (2001) pay for luck
hypothesis. This hypothesis has been spun under the auspice that CEO pay responds as much to a lucky dollar as
to a general dollar. Supporting this hypothesis, controlling for CEO pay economic determinants, and using two
instruments for luck, we define two types of CEO performance based incentive effect; a lucky (systematic)
incentive effect which corresponds to implicit impacts of exogenous events on corporate profitability, and a
purely (specific) incentive effect which reflects human skills and efforts. Consequently, we appoint pay for luck
and pay for performance to design pay sensitivity respectively to each effect.
Finding pay for luck is not new. However, relatively little is known about how pay depends on its nature
that is; are CEOs rewarded for good luck as for bad luck? We show that the answer to this question is a
surrounding no. Besides, although a growing stream of research has linked many financial decisions to
institutional settings, few are the works that have highlighted how the institutional environment affects the
structure of management compensation and its sensitivity to luck. We aim to fill this gap in knowledge by
examining how CEO based performance grants relate to luck and institutional factors. To ascertain the validity
of such factors’ impacts on the systematic incentive effect, we consider the differences made between the Euro-
continental and the Anglo-American corporate governance models regarding the law enforcement level, the
degree of investors’ right protection, and the corporate governance system’s quality.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follow. In the next section, we briefly review research related
to executive pay and specify our hypotheses regarding potential effects of institutional factors on executive pay.
The section thereafter describes the data sources and the methodology that we use. Section 4 describes
robustness checks, while Section 5 concludes.
2 THEORETICAL BACKGROUND AND HYPOTHESIS DEVELOPMENT
2.1 CEO pay theoretical foundations
There is a growing body of literature on CEO performance-based pay. There is, moreover, a large
consensus that the economics of executive remuneration contracts are normally understood in the context of a
principal-agent relationship whereby the manager experiences different incentives to the owner (Jensen and
Meckling, 1976; Gregory-Smith, 2011). We can split the recent related studies into to two groups. The first
group combines works that admit the orthodox (optimal contracting) of the agency approach to assess whether
CEO pay is set by the board to wait on shareholders. Supporting the premises of the hegemony (self-serving)
theory, the second group list together researches that argued that observed compensation contract deviate from
the optimum and that this deviation is contingent on systematic firm performance primarily driven by exogenous
market and industry related factors
1
.
Amongst the first set of theoretical and empirical advancements in the understanding of the management
based performance rewards’ impacts on shareholder value, numerous studies have pointed out that observed
compensations are optimally determined and respond likely to agency concerns. Measuring the magnitude of the
pay-performance correlation has been the standard for good number of these researches for testing the ability of
incentive contracts to enhance corporate profitability. The seminal representative study is that of Jensen and
Murphy (1990). Whereas the authors have failed to find strong evidence of a pay response to performance
2
, rival
1
There are evidences that CEO pay is strongly and positively related to such factors. Researchers supporting these evidences have coined
this relationship as relative performance evaluation, pay for luck, pay for sector performance, etc (Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2001; Garvey
and Milbourn, 2003; 2006; Gopalan et al., 2010; Hoffmann and Pfeil, 2010).
2
Jensen and Murphy (1990) find that the median wealth of a CEO rises by $3.25 when the value of the corporation increases by $1000 for a
sample consisting of CEOs listed in the Forbes Executive Compensation Surveys.
Habib Jouber and Hamadi Fakhfakh
45
studies conducted post the increase in equity based compensation of the 1990s find a much stronger relationship.
These studies cover the U.S. (Hall and Liebman 1998; Core et al., 1999; Harford and Li, 2007; Zheng and Zhou,
2009; Jiménez-Angueira and Stuart, 2010, etc.), Canada (Zhou, 2000; Park et al., 2001; Craighead et al., 2004;
Swan and Zhou, 2006; Chourou et al., 2008; Kalyta and Magnan, 2008; Geremia et al., 2010), France (Alcouffe
and Alcouffe, 2000; Llense, 2010), the U.K. (Ozkan, 2009; Guest, 2009a; Conyon and Sadler, 2010; Voulgaris
et al., 2010; Renneboog and Zaho, 2011), Allemande (Elston and Goldberg, 2003), Australia (Evans and Evans,
2001; Merhebi et al., 2006; Heaney et al., 2010), Japan (Abe et al., 2005; Kato and kubo, 2006), Chine (Conyon
and He, 2011; Chen et al., 2011), Hong Kong (Cheung et al., 2005), Sweden (Oxelheim et al., 2010), Italy
(Brunello et al., 2001), Denmark (Ericksson, 2000), Netherlands (Jansen et al., 2009), Slovenia (Gregoric et al.,
2010), and Portugal (Fernandes, 2008).
A contrario, results from neighbour studies by Tosi et al. (2000) and Gabaix and Landier (2008) may
seem surprising. The authors advocate that firm size accounts for more than 40% of the variance in total CEO
pay while firm performance accounts for only less than 5% and that the 600% increase in CEO pay in US firms
between 1980 and 2003 can be explained by the 600% increase in firm size.
The second set of works is consistent with the view that CEO pay outcome is far from being an agency
problem solution and it may reflect an element of chance (Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2001) or managerial
power (Bebchuk and Fried, 2003; 2004). This view goes further arguing that executives are rewarded for luck
but not for performance. That is, CEOs seem to benefit from windfall earnings beyond their control. Bebchuk et
al. (2006) argue this is likely to be most keenly observed in cases where pay sensitivity to macroeconomic
influences is substantial. When this happen, pay arrangements are viewed as rewarding CEOs’ failures rather
than success. Consequently, modeling CEO compensation with reference to the principal-agent backgrounds
may weaken or mislead shareholders’ overcomes about reward for chance’s dramatic impact on their wealth.
Among researchers arguing against the assumptions that directors could resist the systematic influences and
negotiate at arm’s length with managers under the agency theory, we can mention Bertrand and Mullainathan
(2001), Garvey and Milbourn (2003; 2006), Gopalan et al. (2010), Feriozzi (2011), Oyer (2004), Jiménez-
Angueira and Stuart (2010), Chiu et al. (2011), Oxelheim et al. (2010), Oxelheim and Wihlborg (2003), and
Oxelheim and Randoy (2005).
Bertrand and Mullainathan (2001) question the effectiveness of executive pay as an incentivizing
mechanism. They show that pay for luck is as large as pay for general pay for performance; in other words,
CEOs are rewarded as much to a lucky dollar as to a general dollar. Garvey and Milbourn (2003; 2006) argue
that executives can set pay in their own interests; that is, they can enjoy pay for luck as well as pay for
performance. Gopalan et al. (2010) and Chiu et al. (2011) point out that management can take advantage of
lucky external events and dampen the effects of unlucky external events by taking strategic choices vis-à-vis the
firm’s performance relative to the industry’s performance
3
or exchange rate and macroeconomic fluctuations.
Oyer (2004) find that if managerial outside opportunities are positively related to wide industry movements,
managers might receive a larger pay during an upswing simply because their participation constraints are more
demanding. By considering implicit CEOs’ incentives to avoid bankruptcy in a simple hidden action model,
Feriozzi (2011) documents that luck cannot be filtered out of managerial pay. Jiménez-Angueira and Stuart
(2010)’s study testing whether there is asymmetric use of IRPE and pay-for-luck that indicates CEO power over
the compensation process suggests that CEO bonus compensation is more sensitive to industry-adjusted
performance when the firm outperforms its industry benchmark and when the industry benchmark is positive.
Oxelheim et al. (2010), Oxelheim and Wihlborg (2003), and Oxelheim and Randöy (2005) find macroeconomic
influences on Swedish CEOs’ compensation to be substantial.
In summary, it is striking to notice two interesting findings. First, as related literature mentioned,
management rewards are sensitive to performance as well as to luck. Second, except of Oxelheim et al., (2010),
all cited researches have focused on the U.S. setting. To make sure of the first finding’s truth in other contexts,
we propose our first hypothesis as follow:
Hypothesis 1: CEO pay is sensitive to firm’s performance (specific incentive effect) as much as to luck
(systematic incentive effect) even in non-U.S. countries.
2.2 Institutional features’ impacts on management compensation structure and sensitivity to luck
and performance
Drawing aspiration from La Porta et al.’s (1997) seminal models, a large stream of research has linked
firm’s financial decisions to institutional features. For example La Porta et al. (2000; 2006), Giannetti (2003),
Bartram et al. (2009), Denis and McConnel (2003), Djankov et al. (2008) have established that legal
characteristics affect presumably firm’s decisions regarding dividend pay-out, capital structure, derivatives
usage, financing, and ownership structure
4
. Nevertheless, issues on such features’ impacts on management
3
This is known as Relative Performance Evaluation (RPE).
4
The reader is referred to Bryan et al. (2010) for a thorough review of legal system’s effects on other firm’s financial policies.
Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management / Business-and-Management.org
46
compensation design and international pay difference are scarce. To our knowledge, apart from Bryan et al.
(2010; 2011), no other study has examined if or how institutional environment affects executive compensation.
We extend Bryan et al.’s (2010; 2011) results by addressing whether law enforcement level, investors’ right
protection degree, and the corporate governance system’s quality index are significant determinants of
compensation structure and if international pay differences respond really to variations in these attributes’
strength across countries. The following findings advocate why CEO compensation design and sensitivity to
luck and performance are expected to depend on such attributes and differ across institutional environments.
2.3 Legal system
Legal rules commonly instituted at the national level or exercised within nations may contribute to
between-countries management practices homogeneity (La Porta et al., 1997). Yet, cross national differences in
legal systems may however breed within-countries corporate decisions heterogeneity. We base our hypothesis
on the law and finance theory to explore the possibility that differences in national legal system can lead to
differences in compensation structure. La Porta et al. (1997; 1998) provide undeniable evidence that most
commercial law derives from one of two broad traditions: common law or civil law. The former is based on
English tradition where laws are determined by judges. The latter relies more on statutes and comprehensive
codes which are primarily articulated by legal scholars and governmental authorities. La Porta et al. (1998)
contend that common law systems prevalent in Anglo-Saxon frameworks (such as U.S. and U.K.) provide
significantly stronger protection shareholders’ rights than do civil law ones (such as France). Greater protection
of shareholders’ rights protection has many financial and behavioural implications. First, La Porta et al. (2006)
report that countries with stronger legal protection have more efficient stock markets, but smaller and narrower
debt markets, make so much use of public equity, and rely more on equity based compensation to mitigate
agency costs. Second, Ali and Hwang (2000) show a highly value relevance of accounting information amongst
such countries that provides effective direct link between stock price and firm performance. Third, Bryan et al.,
(2010) point out that common law’s nations are highly democratic and accept further compensation systems that
reward individual talents and achievement. Fourth, Brenner and Schwalbach (2009, p. 3) argue that over the
period 1995-2005, about 9 per cent to 10 per cent flaw of CEOs compensation in the common law countries
have led to a positive pay gap relative to French civil law countries of about U.S. $150,000 per year.
Accordingly, we hypothesize;
Hypothesis 2: In common law countries, CEO pay is more sensitive to firm’s performance than to luck.
2.4 Shareholder rights protection
Under stronger shareholder rights, boards are more accountable for their actions. Shareholder rights are
protected when shareholders are equipped with options that help them to more effectively exercise their control
rights. These rights are enforced by public authorities such us courts or administrative agencies and differ
presumably across jurisdictions. La Porta et al. (1997; 1998), Djankov et al. (2008), Spamann (2006), Brenner
and Schwalbach (2009), and Bryan et al. (2010; 2011) have showed that shareholder protection is guaranteed
within common law system nations. Bryan et al. (2010) have focused on how variation in shareholder rights
protection affects managerial compensation structure. They found evidence that this institutional feature is the
primary determinant of variation in equity mix for a sample of 381 non-US firms from 43 countries during the
1996-2000. Brenner and Schwalbach (2009) contend moreover, that the stronger anti-director rights of
shareholders, the smaller is the risk-adjusted level of CEO pay. Still, they suggest that directors in countries with
higher level of anti-director rights take their duty to achieve the best CEO compensation contract for
shareholders more seriously. On the other hand, shareholder rights enforcement may encourage dutiful
behaviour by executives and deter management self-serving practices. Hence, our third hypothesis reads as
follows:
Hypothesis 3: CEO pay for performance (for luck) is positively (negatively) related to shareholder rights
protection level.
2.5 Corporate governance quality
Several pundits have recognized the potential impact of corporate governance on firm’s financial decisions
and choices. Concerning CEOs pay decisions, there has been an admitted consensus regarding the positive link
between corporate governance and managerial compensation design. For example, the extant literature has
established that equity-based reward is related to compensation committee quality (Sun and Cahan, 2009;
Gregory-Smith, 2011), board independence (Chourou et al., 2008; Ozkan, 2007; Faleye, 2011), institutional
ownership (Hartzell and Starks, 2003; Gallagher et al., 2006), voluntary corporate disclosure (Beyer et al.,
2010), compensation consultants (Murphy and Sandino, 2010; Cadman et al., 2010; Voulgaris et al., 2010), say
on pay (Dew-Becker, 2009; Conyon and Sadler, 2010; Ferri and Maber, 2009). External aspects of corporate
Habib Jouber and Hamadi Fakhfakh
47
governance, such as regulatory environment or the market for CEO talent, influence also both the level and
composition of executive compensation (Sapp, 2008; Geremia et al., 2010; Chalevas, 2011; Cremers and
Grinstein, 2011). Internal and external corporate governance-related factors have moreover, effects on the
association between CEOs pay and firm’s performance. Related empirical literature is full of stories suggesting
too low pay-performance sensitivity in presence of governance failures. In their influential papers, Bertrand and
Mullainathan (2001) and Garvey and Milbourn (2003; 2006) find that in poorly governed firms
5
, managers are
not compensated in line with their performance; that is, they can enjoy pay for luck. Minnick et al. (2010) and
Feriozzi (2011) contend however, that pay-for-performance sensitivity is higher within well governed firms.
Supporting these assertions, we develop our fourth hypothesis as follow:
Hypothesis 4: Well governed firms reward their CEO more for performance than for luck.
3 RESEARCH DESIGN AND METHODOLOGY
In this section, we describe our data, provide our variablesoutline, and ultimately lay out our empirical
methodology.
3.1 Sample selection and data source
This study aims shed light on whether institutional environment features may influence CEO pay structure
and efficiency. To reveal such influence, we consider the distinction made between the Anglo-American and
Euro-Continental corporate governance models. Hence, we select a sample of U.S. and Canadian firms as to
represent the former and a group of U.K. and French firms as to refer to the latter.
Our starting target sample covers a random group of 100 U.S. companies from S&P 500 index, all U.K.
listed firms of the FTSE 100 index, all Canadian companies of TSX100 index, and all firms of SBF 120 index.
The discarding procedure, either because of incomplete needed information for the period under analyses which
covers years from 2004 to 2008, or because of insufficient number of observations per sector, left us with
seventy-five firms in each country. All selected firms are shared out their corresponding industries using the
Fama-French 12 industry classification
6
.
Needed information is hand collected from various sources. For U.S. firms, data on executives’
compensation, ownership structure, board and CEO characteristics are collected from DEF 14A proxy statement
reports available on the SEC files and download from the EdgarScan’s website (edgarscan.com). Financial and
accounting firm’s characteristics come from the 10K annual reports contained in the same database. For the
Canadian firms set, data on CEO pay, ownership and corporate governance are provided by the firms’ proxy
circulars available from the System for Electronic Document Analysis and Retrieval (SEDAR) database. Data
on French observations are exhausted from various sources such as the Expansion, the Financial Market
Authority, and the Euronext websites. Data on the U.K. firms are exclusively collected from their websites
7
.
Shareholder right protection indices are provided by the World Bank Doing Business (2008)’s report.
3.2 Variables selection and measurement
Our dependent variable is measured by the natural logarithm value of cash and equity-based compensation
for the CEO. This logarithm procedure mitigates heteroskedasticity resulting from extreme skewness. Cash
compensation is base salary and bonus. Equity-based compensation is computed as (stock price) × (the member
of newly granted shares) + (stock price) × (option delta) × (the number of newly granted stock options).
We emphasize the effects of institutional factors on executives’ compensation design and sensitivity to
performance and luck. However, the management pay’s academic and practitioner related literature has
suggested a number of economic determinants for CEO compensation. Hence, we include a set of firm’s
(performance, size, growth opportunities, and specific risk) and CEO (managerial horizon, tenure, and
ownership) characteristics to our models as additional explicative variables to facilitate the comparison of our
results with previous studies. Table 1 provides a summary of the measurements for all the variables and their
predicted signs in the regressions.
5
Are firms with concentrated ownership structure, higher entrenched managers, smaller boards, and lower fraction of outside directors.
6
The Fama/French 12 industry classification is: Consumer Non-durables, Consumer Durables, Manufacturing, Energy, Chemicals, Business
Equipment, Telecommunications, Utilities, Shops, Healthcare, and Other. Authors' definitions for these groupings are accessible from
Kenneth R. French's website http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/Data Library/det_12_ind_port.html. The distribution of
the sample firms by industry is available from the authors.
7
Since 2003, listed U.K. companies are required to establish a transparent disclosure for developing policies on executives’ compensation
and corporate issues allowing to more detailed analyses.
Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management / Business-and-Management.org
48
Table1: Variables definition and their predicted effects on executives’ pay
Variable
Label
Predicted
effect
Definition
CEOs compensation
COMP
Natural log of cash and equity-based
compensation for CEO
Institutional factors
Legal system’s origin
LEG
+/-
Equal to 1 if common law, 0 otherwise
Shareholder right protection
SPI
+/-
Shareholder Protection Index from the world
bank doing business (2008) report
Corporate governance quality
G-Ind
+/-
Corporate governance index*
Systematic chocks
Firm’s to industry relative performance
variation
IRPE
+
Variation in the firm’s economic performance
relatively to mean industry’s economic
performance evaluation
Firm’s to market relative performance
variation
MRPE
+
Variation in the firm’s economic performance
relatively to mean market’s economic
performance evaluation
Firm and CEO characteristics
Firm performance
PER
+
Total shareholder return TSR
Firm size
SIZE
+
Total assets in logarithm
Growth opportunities
GROW
+
Market to book ratio ((market value of
equity+ book value of debt)/total assets)
Firm specific risk
RISQ
+
Total risk less systematic risk, where the
latter is estimated using the market model
CEO tenure
TEN
-
Number of years since the CEO is in position
CEO ownership
OWN
-
% of common share owned by the CEO
CEO age
AGE
+
CEO age in years
Note; * This index assigns a value of 1 if the firm meets the threshold level to each of these attributes; chairman and CEO
positions are separated, nominating and compensation committees are composed solely of independent outsiders, board
meet at least twice time annually, at least the CEO serves on the board of one of other public firms, board is controlled by
more than 50% grey directors, and CEO don’t serves as a member neither in the nominating committee, nor in the
compensation committee.
3.3 Models
To test the first hypothesis, we should estimate two sets of models. The first one allows us to estimate the
general sensitivity of pay to performance whereas the second is used to estimate the sensitivity of pay to luck.
The first model is an OLS regression with firm and time fixed effects and can be developed as follows:
(Eq.1)
where COMP
it
is the CEO’s cash and equity-based compensation in firm i at time t; Perf
it
is the total shareholder
return; χ
i
are firm fixed effects; γ
t
are time fixed effects, X
it
are firm, CEO and institutional characteristics, and β
is an estimator to capture the (global) pay-performance link.
The second model helps estimating the sensitivity of pay to luck, that is unobserved chocks that may cause
performance. The most popular way to deal with unobserved causality is to use an Instrumental Variables (I.V.)
approach. To do so, we should identify a valid instrument for the performance measure and estimate model (1)
using two-stage least squares (2SLS). Hence, we estimate as a first stage this equation:
(Eq.2)
where, Chock
it
represents the instrument for luck
8
. In the second stage, 2SLS estimates are obtained by
regressing COMP on the predicted values of Perf, computed using the parameters from the first-stage
regression:
(Eq.3)
8
There are two important characteristics that Chock must have to be a valid instrument. First, it should be sufficiently correlated with Perf,
so we expect η≠0. Second, Chock should be uncorrelated with e, in other words, E[Chock, e] = 0. The insight here is that Chock should not
have its own direct influence on COMP and therefore not be an omitted variable in Equation (1).
Habib Jouber and Hamadi Fakhfakh
49
The estimated coefficient β
luck
captures pay sensitivity to performance that comes from luck (incentive
systematic effect), and F is a vector of the institutional factors. We include industry dummies per the Fama-
French 12 industry classification to each of the three above models.
4 EMPIRICAL RESULTS AND ROBUSTNESS CHECKS
4.1 Descriptive statistics
Table 2 provides the descriptive statistics for the variables in the regression analysis. In panel A, we
observe that the mean (median) cash and equity based compensation of the American and Canadian chief
executive officers, is 6807.195 U.S. million dollars (5904.305 U.S. million dollars). These figures are much
higher in comparison with their counterpart levels in France and U.K. The mean (median) French and British
CEOs compensation is 3890.541 U.S. million dollars (2630.268 U.S. million dollars). The statistics show
however, significant dissimilarities between the two sub-sample specially regarding the institutional features.
On the one hand, it is noteworthy that the Anglo-American framework safeguards shareholder interests more
than the Euro-Continental one. Panel A proves a mean (median) value of shareholder protection index of 6.01
(5.47). Panel B indicates however, values of 4.51 (4.06) which are remarkably lower. On the other hand, U.S.
and Canadian settings show higher level of corporate governance indices when compared to their British and
French peers. Moreover, American and Canadian firms are significantly much larger, exhibit higher growth
opportunities levels, incur less specific risk, and perform well. Notably, French and British CEOs hold relatively
much shares (23.3%) and have larger tenure (11 years). T-statistics for mean differences and Wilcoxon z-scores
for median differences confirm these findings. In fact, univariate difference tests reveal highly significant T-
statistics and z-statistics coefficients
9
.
Pearson correlation matrices show significant pair wise correlations between some explanatory variables.
First, the origin of legal system is highly positively correlated to CEO pay, to shareholder protection index as
well as to governance index (panel A) suggesting that firms from common law countries use greater amount of
cash and equity based compensation, provide greater protection of shareholder rights, and support well qualified
corporate governance tools. Indeed, the significant correlation between these variables is noteworthy. These
univariate links approve, a priori, Bryan et al.’s (2010, 2011) results of the legal system’s positive impacts on
the executive compensation’s equity mix. Second, executive pay is positively correlated with firm size and
performance showing that incentive policies are widely used in large and healthy firms. Two main reasons may
explain this finding: (1) large firms are more likely to hire higher talented managers who can claim and justify
higher compensation and (2) companies with higher performance may also offer higher executive compensation
to further improve their performance. These correlations parallel the ones obtained by Conyon et al. (2010) who
find that size and performance explain by about 37.7% and 28.1% of CEO incentives gap between large and
small firms. Third, we don’t record any association between management reward and CEO characteristics.
Fourth, contrary to the U.S.-Canadian group of firms, we note from panel B that there is no significant link
between executive compensation and any of the institutional factors. Unless, shareholder right protection and
governance quality are highly correlated. We note moreover, a highly positive link between CEO ownership and
top executives compensation within the British-French case. The other statistics are comparable to those
obtained by similar researches dealing with the economic determinants of management incentives.
9
For the sake of brevity, the results of these tests are not reported here. Nevertheless, they are available from the authors under request.
Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management / Business-and-Management.org
50
Table 2: Descriptive statistics and Pearson correlations
Variable
Mean
Median
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
Panel A: U.S.-Canadian sub-sample
1.COMP
3.83
3.77
1
2.LEG
1
-
.18
1
3.SPI
6.01
5.47
.36
.19
1
4.G-Ind
4.38
3.79
.28
.11
.09
1
5.IRPE
0.103
0.07
.13
.02
.01
.03
1
6.MRPE
0.141
0.103
.21
.01
.00
.03
.31
1
7.PER
0.271
0.208
.11
.01
.01
.07
.17
.03
1
8.SIZE
11.45
10.39
.08
.06
.04
.01
.10
.01
.07
1
9.GROW
1.71
1.37
.1
.05
.01
.01
.02
.11
.10
.21
1
10.RISQ
0.033
0.021
.21
.02
.01
.02
-.01
.00
.01
.05
.00
1
11.TEN
9.816
8.039
.09
.01
-.21
-.16
.04
.01
.00
.01
.01
.01
1
12.OWN
0.114
0.093
.01
.01
-.13
-.11
.01
.03
.00
.05
.01
-.1
.20
1
13.AGE
57.97
54.62
.00
.01
.00
.05
.01
.03
.00
.01
.01
.00
.11
.10
1
Panel B: U.K.-French sub-sample
1.COMP
3.59
3.42
1
2.LEG
0.53
0.37
.01
1
3.SPI
4.51
4.06
.01
.01
1
4.G-Ind
4.09
3.37
.03
.00
.11
1
5.IRPE
0.111
0.087
.07
.00
.09
.03
1
6.MRPE
0.107
0.076
.02
.00
.03
.03
.09
1
7.PER
0.173
0.161
.05
.01
.01
.02
.03
.07
1
8.SIZE
8.39
8.07
.10
.01
.01
.01
.01
.02
.05
1
9.GROW
1.19
0.093
.10
.00
.05
.01
.01
.01
.02
.01
1
10.RISQ
0.051
0.037
.05
.04
.00
.00
-.01
-.1
.01
-.1
-.1
1
11.TEN
11.101
9.037
.01
.01
-.01
-.10
.00
.00
.00
.01
.00
.00
1
12.OWN
0.233
0.175
.10
.01
-.10
-.01
.00
.01
.01
.01
.01
-.1
.01
1
13.AGE
59.13
56.83
.05
.01
.01
.01
.00
.01
.00
.01
.00
.01
.05
.1
1
This table presents the univariate analysis of the CEO’s compensation as well as firms and institutional characteristics of
our sub-samples. Panel A (B) shows results for U.S.-Canadian (U.K.-French) sub-sample. Pearson correlations for each
sub-sample appear respectively below the principal diagonal of the correspondent panel. Variable descriptions and
measurement are provided in Table 1. Bold numbers indicate significance at the 1% one-tailed level or better.
4.2 Regression results
The generalized and separated estimation results for the three sets of models are reported in Tables 3 and 4.
Table 3 reports the results of our test of global sensitivity of pay to performance, where performance measure is
the total shareholder return. The first column shows the results of estimating Eq. (1) using the overall
observations. The second and the third columns point out results using sub-sample observations. Models (1a),
(2a), and (3a) include the full independent variables whereas models (1b), (2b), and (3b) control only for
performance and institutional factors. In all specifications, the coefficients for the firm’s performance are
significantly positive indicating that the incentive effect is supported. The magnitude of this effect ranges
between 21% and 39% showing that shareholder wealth rises by nearly one quarter to one third points when the
three highest paid top executives’ cash and equity based compensation increases by one per cent point. This
positive sensitivity of pay to performance is in line with optimal contracting orthodox of the agency approach. It
is noteworthy that the performance’s estimated coefficients are larger in the U.S.-Canadian specification
suggesting that executives’ incentives wait more on American and Canadian shareholders than on British and
French ones. The coefficient for shareholder protection provides strong evidence of positive associations
between the strength of investor rights and the relative use of incentive compensations. The hypothesized effect
of law enforcement quality on executives’ pay is exclusively hold for the U.S.-Canadian sub-sample. The sign
and magnitude of this effect are similar to those reported by Bryan et al. (2010).
Corporate governance quality has also a significant positive impact on CEO compensation. This impact is
notably larger in specifications (2b) and (3b). The coefficient for firm size is significantly positive confirming
univariate analysis that executive pay is positively impacted by firm size. This coefficient is in turn greater than
that of growth opportunities in all models. This difference indicates that although market-to-book ratio has a
positive impact on pay, firm size has a relatively larger impact.
Habib Jouber and Hamadi Fakhfakh
51
Concerning the remainder estimations, the coefficients for the CEO tenure and ownership are the most
noteworthy. The regression estimates of model (3a) show a significant monotone association between the tenure
in the CEO position and the top three executives’ cash and equity based compensation. The coefficient is
economically important (0.139) implying that an increase in the CEO’s tenure by one year will increase
executives’ rewards by roughly 14%. This finding stands in line with the previous evidence of Nourayi and
Mintz (2008). Moreover, the estimate for the CEO ownership is positive and statistically significant at the 1%
level. This is may be consistent with the managerial power approach contending that powerful CEO may
influences the pay process to his own interest.
To further thin the impact of contextual features on executives’ pay, we include interactive variables that
are equal to the shareholder wealth multiplied by each of the three institutional features, that is (TSR
it
× LEG
it
),
(TSR
it
× SPI
it
), and (TSR
it
× G-ind
it
). Unreported results keep constant the previous findings; all interactive
terms are positive and statistically significant (notably for the full and U.S.-Canada sample based regressions).
Table 3: Results of OLS regression analysis of pay-to-performance sensitivity
Variable
Model (1): Full sample
(N=1500)
Model (2): U.S.-Canadian
subsample (N=750)
Model (3): U.K.-French
subsample (N=750)
Model (1a)
Model (1b)
Model (2a)
Model (2b)
Model (3a)
Model (3b)
Intercept
0.058**
(2.2)
0.027***
(2.65)
0.019***
(2.87)
0.024***
(3.06)
0.097**
(2.49)
0.035***
(3.44)
Perf
0.388*
(1.8)
0.37*
(1.64)
0.251**
(2.26)
0.299**
(2.31)
0.217**
(2.09)
0.236**
(1.96)
LEG
0.021*
(1.63)
0.03*
(1.81)
0.105***
(3.01)
0.113***
(2.24)
0.044
(0.96)
0.053
(0.83)
SPI
0.018*
(1.31)
0.021**
(1.96)
0.037**
(2.01)
0.041**
(2.11)
0.022
(0.91)
0.026*
(1.63)
G-Ind
0.011**
(2.41)
0.016**
(2.5)
0.027**
(2.32)
0.031***
(2.73)
0.017*
(1.89)
0.023**
(2.56)
SIZE
0.105**
(2.03)
0.211**
(2.15)
0.177**
(2.01)
GROW
0.091*
(1.87)
0.119**
(1.96)
0.095*
(1.83)
RISQ
0.047
(0.91)
0.031*
(1.81)
0.019
(1.1)
TEN
-0.121*
(-1.76)
-0.1
(1.27)
-0.139**
(-1.96)
OWN
-0.201
(-0.87)
-0.191*
(-1.64)
0.217***
(2.87)
AGE
0.091
(1.03)
0.085
(1.31)
0.107*
(1.8)
Adjusted R
2
0.301
0.498
0.393
0.579
0.377
0.435
This table shows coefficients from the OLS full and separated regression of the CEO pay against shareholder return, firm
and CEO characteristics, and institutional factors. Parameter estimates appear first and standard errors appear in
parenthesis. All models include complete sets of time and industry dummy variables. Variables are as defined in Table 1. *,
**, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% one tailed levels or better respectively.
Table A of the Appendix summarizes estimation results of Eq. (2). Remind that the premise of this
equation is to check firm performance sensitivity to exogenous systematic pressures. That is, we have to
decompose the predicted performance into its ‘real’ part, which is taken cover of these pressures; and its
‘problematic’ part, which is potentially endogenous them. Two interesting observations emerge from the
regression estimates where shareholder wealth is the dependent variable. First, we find that shareholder return is
increasing in the firm’s to industry relative economic performance evaluation and firm’s to market relative
economic performance variation. These interactions show that variations in both relative performance
evaluations are strong instruments for unobservable chocks. Second, firms perform well when growth
opportunities are positively expected, but worst when specific risk is higher and manager is powerful.
To test for the hypothesized systematic incentive effect, we perform the second stage of the instrumental
variables (I.V.) technique. In this stage, 2SLS estimates are obtained by regressing executives’ pay using the
predictable changes in performance due to luck (Pêrf) computed from the first stage. Estimated results appear in
Table 4. From this table, we remarkably note two striking findings. On the one hand, CEO compensation is
positively sensitive to luck. The coefficients for shareholder adjusted return are significantly positive approving
that managers are potentially rewarded for performance beyond their control. Hence, we support our first
hypothesis. It is noteworthy, but not surprising, that firm adjusted performance coefficients are clearly much
Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management / Business-and-Management.org
52
smaller in the U.S.-Canadian sub-sample based regressions showing that firms in these settings reward less for
luck than do their peers in the U.K.-French frameworks. On the other hand, the coefficients for the interaction
between adjusted performance and institutional variables are significantly negative meaning that contextual
factors have moderate effects on the sensitivity of pay-to-luck. The coefficient for the legal system-adjusted
shareholder return interaction term is (-0.194) suggesting that the systematic incentive effect may be mitigated
by until one fifth point when law enforcement quality is sustained. Shareholder right protection and governance
index exert also significant moderate effects on the pay sensitivity to luck. These effects are much conspicuous
for the U.S.-Canadian subsample based regressions. Taken together, these results find straightforward evidence
that systematic incentive effect is more moderate in well governed firms or in those providing strong protection
of shareholder rights. This effect is moreover, less important within nations of common law system. Thus, we
support our expectations regarding the impacts of the specific Anglo-American and Euro-Continental
institutional features on CEO pay sensitivity to luck. Indeed, we rely on previous evidences of pay-for-luck
(Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2001; Garvey and Milbourn, 2003; 2006) and pay-for- firm relative performance
(Farmer et al., 2010; Gopalan et al., 2010; Jiménez-Angueira and Stuart, 2010).
Table 4: Results of 2SLS regression analysis of pay-to-luck sensitivity
Variable
Model (1): Full sample
(N=1500)
Model (2): U.S.-Canadian
subsample (N=750)
Model (3): U.K.-French
subsample (N=750)
Intercept
0.029** (1.96)
0.031** (2.08)
0.047** (2.21)
Pêrf
0.317** (2.11)
0.273*** (2.6)
0.375** (2.31)
LEG* Pêrf
-0.117* (-1.73)
-0.194*** (-3.39)
-0.101* (-1.76)
SPI* Pêrf
-0.201** (-2.27)
-0.270*** (-2.96)
-0.159** (-1.96)
G-Ind* Pêrf
-0.187* (-1.89)
-0.237** (-2.01)
-0.212** (-2.27)
SIZE
0.513* (1.77)
0.308* (1.81)
0.271* (1.88)
GROW
0.317 (1.21)
0.405* (1.7)
0.273 (0.83)
RISQ
0.083 (1.01)
0.117* (1.72)
0.091 (0.82)
TEN
-0.076* (-1.8)
-0.095* (-1.89)
-0.107** (-2.11)
OWN
-0.069* (-1.71)
-0.053 (-0.48)
-0.097** (-2.31)
AGE
0.04 (0.57)
0.034 (1.33)
0.041* (1.73)
Adjusted R
2
0.371
0.596
0.479
This table shows coefficients from the 2SLS full and separated regression of the CEO pay against shareholder adjusted
return, firm and CEO characteristics, and firm performance-institutional factors interaction terms. Parameter estimates
appear first and standard errors appear in parenthesis. All models include complete sets of time and industry dummy
variables. Variables are as defined in Table 1. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% one
tailed levels or better respectively.
4.3 Sensibility analyses
To check for robustness of our results against the unspecified nature of luck, we refer the above tasks after
controlling for the luck nature. Hence, we split each subsample into two groups of firms. We restrict the first
group to just those observations for which the variation in the firm’s to industry relative economic performance
evaluation and/or the variation in the firm’s to market economic performance evaluation is negative (bad luck).
Similarly, we restrict the second group to just those observations for which the variation in these instruments is
positive (good luck)
10
. We define Perf
()
and Perf
(+)
as to refer to the respectively impacts of these specifications
on shareholder return. Check results are shown in Table 5. Such results could normally help us to test whether
pay is similarly sensitive to good luck as to bad luck. We note from this table that the most coefficients of the
Perf
(+)
variable are significantly positive showing that executives’ pay rises presumably when systematic chocks
are favourable. Moreover, we view that the pay-Perf
(+)
links are much reliable in the U.S.-Canadian sub-sample
based estimations than in those ruled on the U.K.-French settings. Unless, the estimation outputs point out that
pay-sensitivity to bad luck is statistically insignificant. Surprisingly, the coefficients for the Perf
()
variable are
positive and significantly different from zero in both models meaning that there is no observable constraining
significant effect of downward systematic pressures on CEOs payment. That is, managers are not penalized
when the market is unfavourable. This finding meets Garvey and Milbourn’s (2006) asymmetry pay-for-luck
thesis which asserts a significantly less CEOs pay for luck when luck is down than when it is up.
The estimated interaction links provide strong support for the moderated impacts of the institutional
variables on the systematic incentive effect when luck is positive. Unless, these absorbed impacts disappear
when luck turns to be negative. The results for firm and CEO characteristics are presumably similar to those
explored above and are conform to evidences of comparable studies.
10
Separating each subsample into two groups has also the advantage of not constraining the coefficients on the performance control
variables to be the same across the two groups of firms.
Habib Jouber and Hamadi Fakhfakh
53
Table 5: Robustness check results
Variable
Model (1): U.S.-Canadian subsample (N=735)
Model (2): U.K.-French subsample (N=670)
Model (1a)
Model (1b)
Model (2a)
Model (2b)
Intercept
0.013* (1.87)
0.01** (1.99)
0.093* (1.83)
0.011* (1.78)
Perf
(+)
0.273** (2.13)
0.362*** (2.89)
Perf
(+)
*LEG
-0.175** (2.07)
-0.106 (1.18)
Perf
(+)
*SPI
-0.319*** (3.01)
-0.211* (1.81)
Perf
(+)
*G-Ind
-0.201** (1.96)
-0.167** (2.21)
Perf
()
0.171** (2.37)
0.202** (2.04)
Perf
()
*LEG
-0.071 (0.34)
-0.056 (0.51)
Perf
()
*SPI
-0.101 (1.11)
-0.117 (0.48)
Perf
()
*G-Ind
-0.19 (0.37)
-0.214 (1.01)
SIZE
0.316** (2.27)
0.271** (2.1)
0.219* (1.83)
0.231* (1.88)
GROW
0.121* (1.78)
0.103* (1.8)
0.107* (1.76)
0.095 (1.34)
RISQ
0.099* (1.88)
0.067* (1.81)
0.084** (2.31)
0.078** (2.2)
TEN
-0.074 (0.32)
-0.058* (1.78)
-0.077* (1.8)
-0.069* (1.86)
OWN
-0.091 (0.11)
-0.059 (1.21)
-0.071** (1.96)
-0.073** (2.03)
AGE
0.068* (1.73)
0.07 (1.35)
0.051* (1.83)
0.066* (1.88)
Adjusted R
2
0.561
0.483
0.601
0.535
This table displays test sensibility results. Perf
(+)
measures the positive variation in the firm’s to industry relative economic
performance evaluation and/or the variation in the firm’s to market economic performance evaluation. Perf
()
measures the
positive variation in the firm’s to industry relative economic performance evaluation and/or the variation in the firm’s to
market economic performance evaluation. Results on full sample estimations are suppressed for expositional convenience.
Parameter estimates appear first, and standard errors appear in parenthesis. All models include complete sets of time and
industry dummy variables. Variables are as defined in Table 1. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%,
5%, and 1% one tailed levels or better respectively.
5 CONCLUSION
The suitability of executive compensation and incentives continues by academics, media, and practitioners.
Nonetheless, some affiliated questions remain unanswered. The premise of this paper is to address the
followings; Are CEOs rewarded for luck? Do institutional features matter for CEOs pay for luck? How does
systematic incentive effect sensitive to luck’s nature?
By answering these questions, we attempt several contributions to the management pay literature. Our first
contribution is to extend this literature by investigating still not sufficiently investigated research fields. To do
so, we tackle the Anglo-American and the Euro-Continental corporate governance areas. Numerous contextual
factors differ across these frameworks and may presumably explain the remarkable differences in executive pay
between them. From these factors we select the legal system’s origin, the shareholders’ rights protection, and the
corporate governance quality. Links between these features and firms’ financial decisions have been largely
studied. Nevertheless, their impacts on CEO pay structure and sensitivity to performance and systematic chocks
are not still explored. Revealing these impacts forms our second contribution. Our last contribution is to approve
the asymmetric character of the systematic incentive effect using instruments for luck not rounded up before.
Taken together, several results from the paper provide answers to the above questions and stand out as new
or important. We find that the answers for to the two first questions are a surrounding yes. On the one hand,
instrumental variables estimators show that the coefficients for the adjusted (to luck) shareholder return are
significantly positive showing that CEOs, in both settings, are potentially rewarded for luck. That is, for
systematic chocks beyond their control. Per sub-sample analysis clarify that Anglo-American managers benefit
more from luck than their European peers. On the other hand, we provide evidence that the selected institutional
factors are the primary determinants of pay intensity and sensitivity to performance and to luck. Especially, we
find that CEO pay to performance elasticity is positively associated with the strength of shareholder rights, the
quality of corporate governance tools, and the level of law enforcement. Pay to luck sensitivity is however,
significantly strong within nations where these features are less sustained. Consequently, we support the two
agency approach’s orthodox previously claimed by Bertrand and Mullainathan (2001); well governed firms fit
the predictions of the contracting view whereas, poorly governed ones fit those of the skimming view.
By discerning favourable exogenous chocks (good luck) from unfavourable ones (bad luck), we agree
Garvey and Milbourn’s (2006) and Gopalan et al.’s (2010) pay for luck asymmetry theses; executive are
rewarded for good luck while they are insulated from bad luck. Or, otherwise, CEO pay-setting process involves
‘carrots’ (rewards for high performance), rather than ‘sticks’ (punishment for poor performance).
Even though our findings answer the above addressed questions, other CEO pay determinants are still to
be decided. Further researches are needed in order to have a full understanding of some of these determinants.
Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management / Business-and-Management.org
54
As further directions, future studies should highlight the impacts of cultural, ethical, and political countries
specific factors on the management compensation contracts design and efficiency.
APPENDIX
Table A: Results of the first stage of the instrumental variables (I.V.) estimation approach
Variable
Model (1): Full sample
(N=1500)
Model (2): U.S.-Canadian
subsample (N=750)
Model (3): U.K.-French
subsample (N=750)
Model (1a)
Model (1b)
Model (2a)
Model (2b)
Model (3a)
Model
(3b)
Intercept
0.068*
(1.67)
0.051*
(1.88)
0.077**
(2.01)
0.056*
(1.89)
0.039**
(1.96)
0.045*
(1.68)
IRPE
0.135***
(3.39)
0.71**
(2.46)
0.644***
(3.14)
MRPE
0.41**
(2.26)
0.56**
(2.00)
0.77***
(2.88)
SIZE
0.031
(1.01)
0.023
(0.86)
0.019*
(1.81)
0.011*
(1.89)
0.027
(1.33)
0.03*
(2.11)
GROW
0.053
(1.22)
0.047*
(1.88)
0.071**
(1.96)
0.059**
(2.11)
0.037*
(1.89)
0.028*
(1.9)
RISQ
-0.049*
(1.81)
-0.031*
(1.81)
-0.017**
(1.96)
-0.022*
(1.88)
-0.037**
(2.07)
-0.044**
(2.13)
TEN
0.001
(1.21)
0.001
(1.01)
0.01
(0.86)
0.018
(0.91)
0.022*
(1.86)
0.019
(1.31)
OWN
-0.02*
(1.87)
-0.017
(1.33)
-0.023*
(1.8)
-0.027**
(1.96)
-0.036***
(2.87)
-0.041***
(3.08)
AGE
-0.001
(0.83)
0.007
(0.76)
-0.011
(1.11)
-0.009
(0.53)
0.017
(1.01)
0.011
(1.27)
Adjusted R
2
0.173
0.131
0.27
0.249
0.314
0.298
This table shows coefficients from the I.V. estimation of the firm performance sensitivity to luck due to unobserved chocks.
Variation in the firm’s to industry relative economic performance evaluation and variation in the firm’s to market economic
performance evaluation are used as instruments for luck. Dependent variable is shareholder total return. Parameter
estimates appear first and standard errors appear in parenthesis. All models include complete sets of time and industry
dummy variables. Variables are as defined in Table 1. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and
1% one tailed levels or better respectively.
REFERENCES
Abe, N., Gaston, N., & Kubo, K., (2005). Executive pay in Japan: the role of bank appointed monitors and the
main bank relationship. Japan and the World Economy, 17, 371394.
Alcouffe, A., & Alcouffe, C., (2000). Executive compensation setting practices in France. Long Range
Planning, 33 (4), 527-543.
Ali, A., & Hwang, L., (2000). Country specific factors related to financial reporting and the value relevance of
accounting data. Journal of Accounting Research, 38, 1-21.
Bartram, S., Brown, G., & Fehle, F., (2009). International evidence on financial derivatives usage. Financial
Management, 38, 185-206.
Bebchuk, L.A., & Frield, J.M., (2003). Executive compensation as an agency problem. Journal of Economic
Perspective, 17, 71-92.
Bebchuk, L.A., & Frield, J.M., (2004). Pay without performance; the unfulfilled promise of executive
compensation. Harvard University Press.
Bebchuk, L.A., Grinstein, Y., & Peyer, U., (2006). Lucky CEOs. NBER Working Paper Series.
Bertrand, M., & Mullainathan, S., (2001). Are CEOs rewarded for luck? The ones without principals are. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116 (3), 901-932.
Beyer, A., Cohen, A., D., Lys, Z., T., & Walther, R., B., (2010). The financial reporting environment: Review of
the recent literature. Journal of Accounting and Economics, in press.
Brenner, S., & Schwalbach, J., (2009). Legal institutions, board diligence, and top executive pay. Corporate
Governance: An International Review, 17 (1), 1-12.
Habib Jouber and Hamadi Fakhfakh
55
Brunello, G., Graziano, C., & Parigi, B., (2001). Executive compensation and firm performance in Italy.
International Journal of Industrial Organization, 19 (1-2), 133-161.
Bryan, S., Nash, R., & Patel, A., (2010). How the legal system affects the equity mix in executive compensation.
Financial Management, spring 2010, 393-418.
Bryan, S., Nash, R., & Patel, A., (2011). Law and executive compensation: a cross-country analysis. Applied
Corporate Finance, 23 (1), 84-91.
Cadman, B., Carter, E., M., & Hillegeist, S., (2010). The incentives of compensation consultants and CEO pay.
Journal of Accounting and Economics, 49, 263-280.
Chalevas, G., C., (2011). The effect of the mandatory adoption of corporate governance mechanisms on
executive compensation. The International Journal of Accounting, 46, 138-174.
Chen, J., Ezzamel, M., & Cai, Z., (2011). Managerial power, tournament theory and executive pay in China.
Working paper. Cardiff University.
Cheung, Y., Stouraitis, A., & Yong, A.W.S., (2005). Ownership concentration and executive compensation in
closely held firms: evidence from Hong Kong. Journal of Empirical Finance, 12, 511-532.
Chiu, H., S., Oxelheim, L., & Wihlborg, C., (2011). Exchange rate and macroeconomic fluctuations as sources
of luck in CEO compensation. SSRN working paper, abstract=1928959.
Chourou, L., Abaoub, E., & Saadi, S., (2008). The economic determinants of CEO stock options compensation.
Journal of Multinational Financial Management, 18, 61-77.
Conyon, M., & He, L., (2011). Executive compensation and corporate governance in China. Journal of
Corporate Finance, 17, 1158-1175.
Conyon, M., J., Peck, S., I., & Sadler, G., V., (2009). Compensation consultants and executive pay: Evidence
from the United States and the United Kingdom. Academy of Management Perspectives, 23 (1), 43-55.
Conyon, M., & Sadler, G., (2010). Shareholder voting and directors’ remuneration report legislation: say on pay
in the UK. Corporate Governance: An International Review, (18) 4, 296-312.
Core, J., Holthausen, R., & Larcker, D., (1999). Corporate governance, chief executive officer compensation,
and firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 51 (3), 371-406.
Craighead, J., Magnan, M., & Thorne, L., (2004). The impact of mandated disclosure on performance-based
CEO compensation. Contemporary Accounting Research, 21 (2), 369398.
Cremers, M., & Grinstein, Y., (2011). The Market for CEO Talent: Implications for CEO Compensation. SSRN
Working paper, available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1108761.
Denis, D., & McConnell, J., (2003). International corporate governance. Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis, 1 (1), 1-36.
Dew-Becker, I., (2009). How Much Sunlight Does it Take to Disinfect a Boardroom? A Short History of
Executive Compensation Regulation in America. CESifo Economic Studies, 55 (3-4), 434457.
Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A., (2008). The law and economics of self-dealing.
Journal of Financial Economics, 88, 430-465.
Elston, J. A., & Goldberg, L. G., (2003). Executive compensation and agency costs in Germany. Journal of
Banking and Finance, 27, 1391-1410.
Eriksson, T., (2000). What determines managers pay? Evidences from Denmark. Long Range Planning, 33 (4),
544-559.
Evans, R., & Evans, J., (2001). The influence of non-executive director control and rewards on CEO
remuneration: Australian evidence, working paper (Curtin University of Technology, Perth, WA).
Faleye, O., (2011). CEO directors, executive incentives, and corporate strategic initiatives. The Journal of
Financial Research, 34 (2), 241-277.
Farmer, M., A., Alexandrou, G., & Archbold, S., (2010). New evidence of relative performance evaluation
(RPE) in UK chief executive realized incentive compensation. Working paper, Kingston Business School.
Feriozzi, F., (2011). Paying for observable luck. RAND Journal of Economics, 42 (2), 387415.
Fernandes, N., G., (2008). Board compensation and firm performance: the role of ‘independent’ board members.
Journal of Multinational Financial Management, 18, 30-44.
Ferri, F., & Maber, D., A., (2009). Say on pay vote CEO compensation: Evidence from the UK. Harvard
Business School and SSRN.
Gabaix, X., & Landier, A., (2008). Why has CEO pay increased so much? Quarterly Journal of Economics,
123, 49100.
Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management / Business-and-Management.org
56
Gallagher, D., R., Smith, G., & Swan, P., (2006). Do institutional investors really monitor executive
compensation? Mimeo.
Garvey, T., G., & Milbourn T., T., (2003). Incentive Compensation When Executives Can Hedge the Market:
Evidence of Relative Performance Evaluation in the Cross Section. Journal of Finance, 58, 1557-1581.
Garvey, T., G., & Milbourn, T., T., (2006). Asymmetric benchmarking in compensation: executives are
rewarded for good luck but not penalized for bad. Journal of Financial Economics, 82, 179-225.
Geremia, K., Carnaghan, C., & Nelson, T., (2010). Exploring changes in management compensation structure in
Canada; evidence on consequences of requiring options expensing. Working paper, University of
Lethbridge.
Giannetti, M., (2003). Do better institutions mitigate agency problems? Evidence from corporate finance
choices. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 38, 185-212.
Gopalan, R., Milbourn, T., & Song, F., (2010). Strategic Flexibility and the Optimality of Pay for Sector
Performance. Review of Financial Studies, 23 (5), 20602098.
Gregoric, A., Polanec, S., & Slapnicar, S., (2010). Pay me right: reference values and executive compensation.
European Financial Management, 16 (5), 778-804.
Gregory-Smith, I., (2011). Chief executive pay and remuneration committee independence. Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics, 1-22.
Guest, M., P., (2009a). Board structure and executive pay: evidence from the UK. Cambridge Journal of
Economics, 1-22.
Hall, B., & Liebman, J., (1998). Are CEOs really paid like bureaucrats? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 133,
653-691.
Harford, J., Li, K., (2007). Decoupling CEO wealth and firm performance: The case of acquiring CEOs. Journal
of Finance, 62 (2) , 917-949.
Hartzell, J. C., & Starks, L. T., (2003). Institutional investors and executive compensation. The Journal of
Finance, 58, 2351-2374.
Heaney, R.,Tawani, V., & Goodwin, J., (2010). Australian CEO Remuneration. Economic Papers, 29 (2), 109
127.
Hoffmann, F., & Pfeil, S., (2010). Reward for luck in a dynamic agency model. The Revue of Financial Studies,
23 (9), 3329-3345.
Holmstrom, B., (1979). Moral hazard and observability. Bell Journal of Economics, 10 (1), 74-91.
Jansen, P., E., Merchant, A., K., & Van der Stede, A., W., (2009). National differences in incentive
compensation practices: the differing roles of financial performance measurement in the United States and
the Netherlands. Accounting, Organization and Society, 34 (1), 58-84.
Jensen, M., & Murphy, K., (1990). Performance pay and top management incentives. Journal of Political
Economy, 22 (2), 225-264.
Jensen, M.C., & Meckling, W., (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership
structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3 (4), 305-360.
Jiménez-Angueira, C., & Stuart, V., N., (2010). CEO Bonuses, Relative Performance Evaluation, and Pay-for-
Luck. SSRN working paper, abstract= 1691154.
Kalyta, P., & Magnan, M., (2008).Stealth compensation: The case of supplemental executive retirement plans.
Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 27 (2), 101-194.
Kato, K., & Kubo, K., (2006). CEO Compensation and firm performance in Japan: Evidence from new panel
data on individual CEO Pay. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 20, 1-19.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (2006). What works in securities laws? Journal of
Finance, 61 (1), 1-32.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R., (1997). Legal determinants of external finance.
Journal of Finance, 52 (3), 1131-1150.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R., (1998). Law and finance. The Journal of Political
Economy, 106, 1113-1155.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R., (2000). Investor protection and corporate
governance. Journal of Financial Economics, 58, 3-27.
Llense, F., (2010). French CEO’s compensation: what is the cost of a mandatory upper limit? CESifo Economic
Studies, Jun 56 (2), 165-191.
Habib Jouber and Hamadi Fakhfakh
57
Merhebi, R., Pattenden, K., Swan, P., L., & Zhou, X., (2006). Australian Chief Executive Officer Remuneration:
Pay and Performance. Accounting and Finance, 46, 48197.
Minnick, K., Unal, H., & Yang, L., (2011). Pay for performance? CEO compensation and acquirer returns in
BHCs. The Review of Financial Studies, 24 (2), 339-472.
Murphy, K., & Sandino, T., (2010). Executive pay and “independent” compensation consultants. Journal of
Accounting and Economics, 49, 247-262.
Nourayi, M. M., & Mintz, M. S., (2008). Tenure, firm’s performance, and CEO compensation. Managerial
Finance, 34 (8), 524-536.
Oxelheim, L., & Randoy, T., (2005). The Anglo-American financial influence on CEO compensation in non-
Anglo-American firms. Journal of International Business Studies, 36 (4), 470-483.
Oxelheim, L., & Wihlborg, C., (2003). Recognizing macroeconomic fluctuations in value based management.
Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 15 (4), 104-110.
Oxelheim, L., Wihlborg, C., & Zhang, J., (2010). How to Avoid Compensating CEO for Luck: The Case of
Macroeconomic Fluctuations. IFN Working Paper No. 842.
Oyer, P., (2004). Why do firms use incentives that have no incentive effects? Journal of Finance, 59, 1619
1649.
Ozkan, N., (2007). Do corporate governance mechanisms influence CEO compensation? An empirical
investigation of UK companies. Journal of Multinational Financial Management, 17 (5), 349-364.
Ozkan, N., (2009). CEO compensation and firm performance: an empirical investigation of UK panel data.
European Financial Management, (12), 1-26.
Park, Y., Nelson, T., & Huson, M., (2001). Executive pay and the disclosure environment: Canadian evidence.
Journal of Financial Research, 24 (3), 347-365.
Renneboog, L., & Zhao, Y., (2011). Us knows us in the UK: on directors networks and CEO compensation.
Journal of Corporate Finance. Article in press.
Sapp, G., M., (2008). The impact of corporate governance on executive compensation. European Financial
Management, 14 (4), 710-746.
Spamann, H., (2006). On the insignificance and/or endogeneity of La Porta et al.’s “anti director rights index”
under consistent coding. Working paper n°7, Harvard Law School, Cambridge.
Sun, J., & Cahan, S., (2009). The effect of compensation committee quality on the association between CEO
cash compensation and accounting performance. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 17 (2),
193-207.
Swan, P., & Zhou, X., (2006). Does executive compensation disclosure alter pay at the expense of incentives?
Unpublished working paper, Australian School of Business UNSW and University of Hong Kong.
Tosi, H., Werner, S., Katz, J., & Gomez-Mejia, L., R., (2000). A meta-analysis of executive compensation
studies. Journal of Management, (26), 301-339.
Voulgaris, G., Stathopoulos, K., & Walker, M., (2010). Compensation consultants and CEO pay: UK evidence.
Corporate Governance: An International Review. Article in press.
Zheng, L., & Zhou, Z., (2009). The Effect of Executive Stock Options on Firm Performance: Evidence from
retiring CEOs, SSRN working paper, abstract= 1426540.
Zhou, X., (2000). CEO pay, firm size, and corporate performance: evidence from Canada. The Canadian
Journal of Economics, 33 (1), 213251.