Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management, Volume 11, Issue 1, 2016
Extrinsic Motivation Index: A New Tool for Managing Labor
Productivity
Sergio A. Berumen
Department of Applied Economics I
Faculty of Law and Social Sciences
King Juan Carlos University
Pº de los Artilleros, s/n. 28032, Madrid Spain
Phone: + 34 91 488 7671
Email: sergio.berumen@urjc.es
Luis P. Pérez-Megino
Department of Industrial Economics & Management
The Royal Institute of Technology - KTH
Lindstedtsyägen, 30. 114 28, Stockholm Sweden
Phone: +46 79 348 28 45
Email: luispe@kth.se
Karen Arriaza Ibarra
Department of Audiovisual Communication & Advertising I
Faculty of Information Sciences
Complutense University of Madrid
Av. Complutense, s/n. 28040, Madrid Spain
Phone: + 34 91 394 7141
Email: arriazaibarra@ccinf.ucm.es
Abstract
The objective of this paper is to provide a tool of practical significance for HR managers and firm
executives. This tool, which is called Extrinsic Motivation Index (EMI), is meant to measure the extrinsic
motivation of employees. By measuring employees’ extrinsic motivation, managers are able to track job
satisfaction and, subsequently, implement measures aiming both to raise job satisfaction and to improve
organizational commitment. In order to test the validity of the model, we apply the EMI to Faculty
members at Spanish and German universities. We also carry out simulation experiments in order to to
address all possible situations an organization most probably will have to deal with. The results point out
significant differences in the level of motivation and commitment of Faculty members. Additionally, the
analysis shows several ways in which an organization may manage job satisfaction issues according to on
its level of resources.
Keywords: motivation, job satisfaction, human resources, statistical methods.
Acknowledgements: The authors would like to thank Bryan van Scoyk, Matthias Engström and Julia
Fehrmann for the field work they carried out during the development of this research. Luis P. Pérez-
Megino would also like to thank Fundación Ramón Areces for providing the financial support needed for
this research.
Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management / Business-and-Management.org
2
1 INTRODUCTION
The rise of globalization has shaken the conventional paradigm, affecting both the social and
economic environments of the organization. Thus, it is not surprising that Human Resource Management
(HRM) has been significantly affected. Historically, we have witnessed the managing of human resources
since the first organization of people into functioning units, as in the case of tribes. Adam Smith’s
seminal work An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations highlighted the division
of labor in which different persons craftsmen were allocated into different roles in the production
process. Whether managed through the natural functioning of a tribal leader or through the personnel
management of an industrial firm, the managing of human resources is something that has always been
present in most firms.
Around 1800, Robert Owen somewhat introduced in England the welfare system into private
business, improving both social and working for the employees conditions (Dulebohn et al., 1995). Over
time, these systems evolved into more elaborated systems where workers were provided with social
services for the family unit, such as education, insurance, and pensions (Davis, 1957). These welfare
systems were mainly designed to promote proper worker relations and to increase productivity (Dulebohn
et al., 1995). Unsurprisingly, these practices were targeted as the starting point of the different techniques
used today to attract, motivate, and retain workers. The evolution, however, has been significant: whereas
those welfare programs were initially designed to benefit businesses, today’s HRM programs are focused
on the satisfaction of both employers and employees.
In fact, the study of HRM has a brief history. It was 1901 when the President of National Cash
Register Co. decided to set-up a separate department for HRM
1
in the United States (Denisi et al., 2014).
Later on, other companies such as Ford, GM or Bethlehem Steel carried out similar operations. When
Western Electric
2
argued that employees’ attitudes were related to productivity, major companies began
to see potential in keeping their employees satisfied, and so the human relations era was born. During the
1950s, the Human Relations movement challenged the traditional assumption that people do not want to
work, stressed the role of the human resources department, and emphasized that human resources are
assets to organizations and that the way in which HR are managed does, in fact, matter. The last quarter
of the 20
th
century witnessed the changes that led to the current mode of operations. By the 1980s,
managers came to realize that if they hired the right people, trained them and rewarded them properly,
these employees could actually be the source of some competitive advantage. As it became clear that
human resources are critical for the correct functioning of organizations, HRM assumed a new strategic
function (Kochan et al., 1986). It is this rising interest in managing HR and increasing productivity what
motivates this paper.
Although there are compelling reasons to believe that research has improved the understanding and
quality of HRM procedures, there are academics (Saari and Judge, 2004; Hambrick, 2007; Rousseau,
2007; DeNisi et al., 2014; etc.) who advise researchers to make research more relevant, or at least more
useful for organizations. DeNisi et al. (2014) complained about the existing gap between HR research and
practice, and stressed the relevance of making use of the information that comes out of research. In their
view, scholars are too often focused on issues that in practice are insignificant. Accordingly, Hambrick
(2007) points out that strong theory has replaced practical significance in the best journals. By the same
token, Rousseau (2007) suggests that academicians need to explain how research findings can be
translated into practice.
This paper aims to answer the criticism that comes from both executives and scholars. Especially, it tries
to provide a method designed to measure employee attitudes, highly demanded by Saari and Judge
(2004). Thus, we focus on providing a tool of practical significance, although a strong theoretical
framework is still needed. This tool, which we will refer to as Extrinsic Motivation Index (EMI), is
meant to measure the extrinsic motivation of employees
3
. By measuring employees’ extrinsic motivation,
managers could track job satisfaction and, subsequently, implement measures aiming both to raise job
satisfaction and to improve organizational commitment. The benefits from relying on such a tool are
1 
2 As a result of the Hawthorne Studies, performed between 1925 and 1937.
3 Extrinsic motivation is the sort of motivation in which managers can exert some influence on. Intrinsic motivation
(IM) is found to depend only on individual preferences. This will be thoroughly discussed in the Literature Review
section.
Berumen Sergio A., Pérez-Megino Luis P. and Arriaza Ibarra Karen
3
quite substantial, as we will argue in later sections. From tracking employees’ motivation to know how to
improve organizational commitment
4
, we put a valuable tool at the disposal of managers and CEOs.
In this section we shortly introduced the object of study. The rest of the paper is organized as
follows. In section II we present the complete body of previous research, as well as set the links among
motivation, job satisfaction and productivity. In Section III we discuss the methodology used and develop
the according Extrinsic Motivation Index (EMI). Section III also tries to prove the usefulness of the
empirical tool by addressing the motivation of Faculty members in three European universities, to know:
Freie Universität and Humboldt Universität zu Berlin (both from Germany), and Spanish Universidad
Rey Juan Carlos (URJC). Seeking to test the relevance of the EMI in different scenarios, simulation
experiments are also carried out in this section. Finally, Section IV aims to put all pieces together and it
also comments the limitations of EMI, emphasizing the conclusions of our research, and by making new
questions that need to be further explored in future research.
2 LITERATURE REVIEW
The performance of employees is the most important factor that affects the success of institutions. In
fact, some scholars have pointed out that motivation is a prerequisite for an effective social and economic
activity (Colesca, 2010). Throughout centuries, thinkers and philosophers have tried to identify and
explain what motivates people to perform activities. Seneca (2014, pp. 41-42) affirmed: “All men wish to
make things, but in the process of discovering what stimulates them they wander off track”. During the
20
th
century economists also tried although implicitly to explain motivation. They focused, however,
on goals of a more fiscal or monetary nature, i.e. they assumed that higher employment and lower
inflation rates would make us happier, more motivated human beings. In recent years we have
experienced a revival in the interest for motivation, benefitting from ideas with broader views in about
what motivates people which serves to motivate people. Several studies (Bruni and Porta, 2006; Van
Praag and Ferrer-i-Carbonell, 2008; Aziri, 2011; Saager et al., 2012) have deepened our understanding of
what is to be meant by “motivation”, and what are the most adequate instruments to encourage it. The
aforementioned literature agrees when it says that motivation not only increases work productivity, but is
also a decisive element for emotional wellbeing. For this reason it is vital to identify the factors that
increase work motivation and its measurement, both for the benefit of the employee, who will see
satisfaction increased in the development of his activity, and for the employers, who will be able to
maximize productivity.
2.1 Linking Motivation and Productivity
Diverse factors such as the level of investment in capital goods, the development of new
technologies, larger innovation processes, or a complex blend of institutional and human factors,
determine productivity. Among these, human variables include workers’ skills and the effort required to
develop their work. Therefore we can affirm that: i) personal effort is directly related to motivation
(White, 1959); and ii) personal effort has a direct impact on productivity (Mahoney, 1988). But what does
motivation mean?
2.2 Concept of Motivation
Motivation has been analyzed over time and it dates back to Ancient Greece. However, modern
academic research was not carried out until 1920s, when the Psychological Review published the work of
English (1921), Wolfe (1921), and Perrin (1923). Since the first publications appeared, motivation has
never left academic research. In fact, according to the Web of Science search results, there have been
more than 210.000 researches related to motivation. Today’s most-widely accepted definition of work
motivation is the outlined by Pinder (1984), which is consistent with later formulations coming from
motivation theorists such as Landy and Becker (1987), Ford (1992), and Latham and Pinder (2005). Work
motivation is defined by Pinder (2008, pp. 11) as “a set of energetic forces that originate both within as
well as beyond an individual’s being, to initiate work-related behavior, and to determine its form,
direction, intensity and duration”. It is widely accepted that motivation is primarily two-dimensional,
referring to intrinsic and extrinsic. Intrinsic motivation involves persons performing an activity because
they get satisfaction from their own performance (White, 1959; Berlyne, 1960). Their behaviors are
driven by curiosity, pursuit of knowledge and skill acquisition, even in the absence of rewards. On the
other hand, extrinsic motivation is the connection between the performance of an activity and its sudden
4 Organizational commitment could be improved through a vast selection of alternatives, such as a better
               
environment.
Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management / Business-and-Management.org
4
reward, such as monetary or verbal prizes, so that satisfaction does not come from the activity itself, but
through extrinsic rewards related to the activity. In addition to these sorts of motivation, it is necessary to
consider that individuals can also feel demotivated.
2.3 Extrinsic Motivation
Extrinsic motivation has been previously defined as the connection between the performance of an
activity and its sudden reward. It seems clear that extrinsic rewards improve the performance of an
activity in the absence of intrinsic motivation. And in most activities people are not intrinsically
motivated because of the routine. Satisfaction comes from the reward rather than the activity itself. Miller
(1944) recognized two goals to focus on: approach and avoidance. In approach motivation, behavior is
directed by a positive or desirable event, whereas in avoidance motivation, behavior is directed by a
negative or undesirable event (Elliot, 1999). The importance of avoidance motivation must be
acknowledged when thinking of motivation as a whole. For Instance, in Herzberg’s (1957) Two-Factor
model, avoidance of loss is a great motivator.
2.4 Linking Motivation and Job Satisfaction
In order to develop the previously mentioned Extrinsic Motivation Index, the vast literature on job
satisfaction (e.g. Theory of Work Adjustment) needs also to be considered. Arguably, there is a close
relationship between motivation, job satisfaction and job performance (Kahya, 2008; Yang, 2010). Job
satisfaction impacts on the motivation of workers, while the level of motivation impacts productivity and,
thus, the performance of organizations (Aziri, 2011). Job satisfaction attempts to identify how content an
individual is with his or her job and all that it entails (Spector, 1997). It has been found to significantly
influence absenteeism, turnover, the quantity of work performed, the tardiness rate, commitment level,
job performance, and psychological distress (Silverthorne, 2004; Chen et al., 2006; Griffin and
Moorhead, 2014).
However, the linkages between motivation and job satisfaction are certainly diffuse. In the past few
decades, researchers have explained the motivation of HR from different perspectives (Pritchard, 2008;
Munir, 2011), in most cases combining characteristics from several theoretical models. To begin with, we
must refer to Maslow’s (1943) pioneering paper, which introduced the Hierarchy of Needs. Later on, we
have witnessed the appearance of a diversified branch of theories, such as Adams’ (1965) Equity Theory,
Hertzberg’s (1968) Two-Factor Theory, Porter and Lawler’s (1968) improvement of Vroom’s (1964)
Theory, Locke’s (1969) Discrepancy Theory, Alderfer’s (1969) ERG Model, Hackman and Oldham’s
(1976) Job Characteristics Model, Locke’s (1976) Range of Affect Theory, Bandura’s (1977) Social
Learning Theory, Landy’s (1978) Opponent Process Theory, Deci and Ryan’s (1985) Organismic
Integration Theory (OIT), Caplan’s (1987) Person-Environment Fit Theory, McClelland’s (1988) Human
Motivation Theory, Deci and Ryan’s (2000) Self-Determination Theory (SDT), to just name the more
popular. Table 1 displays a brief summary of those theoretical approaches we consider more relevant
when constructing the EMI.
Table 1: Brief Summary of the Theoretical Approaches Relevant to the Construction of the EMI.
Theoretical Tradition
Argument
Cognitive Evaluation
Theory (CET)
External factors, such as tangible rewards, monitoring, assessment and delivery deadlines
tend to decrease feelings of autonomy and undermine intrinsic motivation. It also specifies
that a competitive environment does not increase intrinsic motivation unless a locus of
autonomy understood as the ability of a person to lead their life is given. Later it was
found that tangible rewards significantly undermine intrinsic motivation.
Self-Determination Theory
(SDT)
SDT asserts that humans are motivated by three basic psychological needs: for competence,
relatedness, and autonomy. When an individual's three needs are fully satisfied, engagement
in action is intrinsically motivated and promotes adaptive development and well-being.
When one of the needs is unsatisfied, engagement is likely to be extrinsically motivated and
development may be hindered. SDT suggests a greater degree of extrinsic motivation has a
greater influence on motivation when enjoying some freedom and willingness to perform
tasks.
Person-Environment Fit
Theory
Person-Environment fit is focused on providing predictions on how personal and
environmental factors impact results. Therefore, inferences can be made about the
match/mismatch of a person with the environment in which he/she works. Personal variables
(P) refer to the value people attach to rewards. In principle it recognizes that rewards are
positive. A high degree of adjustment predicts several positive results, while, generally, a
mismatch predicts greater stress, tension, and negative results. Csikszentmihalyi (1990)
identified that in both cases, when rewards exceed a certain value, it can foster negative
effects.
Berumen Sergio A., Pérez-Megino Luis P. and Arriaza Ibarra Karen
5
Crowding-out Theory
This approach is based on the crowding-out effect, to the extent that external rewards are
introduced, it highlights the capability of moving and minimizes the intrinsic motivation
levels.
Social/Justice Comparison
Theories
Social/Justice comparison theory is centered on the belief that there is a need within
individuals to compare with each other. The theory explains how individuals evaluate their
own opinions and abilities by comparing themselves to others. Following the initial theory,
research began to focus on social comparison as a way of self-enhancement, introducing the
concepts of downward and upward comparisons. Downward social comparisons are likely to
make us feel better, while upward social comparisons are likely to motivate us to achieve our
goals. We find several models of Social comparison: Self-Evaluation Maintenance Model,
the Proxy Model, the Triadic Model, and the Three-Sleeves Model.
Cognitive-Interactional
Theories
Within this large branch of theories we can identify: i) Social Cognitive Theory, which is
focused on social interactions and experiences. According to this theory, depending on
whether people are rewarded or punished for their behavior, their behavior may be modeled;
ii) Vroom’s Expectancy Theory (1964), which provides a process of cognitive variables that
reflects individual differences in work motivation. It allows to identify what factors affect
employees’ motivation (such as economic rewards) and what can be done to alter it; and iii)
Attribution Theory, which is primarily focused on explaining behaviors.
3 THE EXTRINSIC MOTIVATION INDEX (EMI)
Research has suggested that it is possible to increase productivity and employees’ quality of work
life through the manipulation of job-related variables (Korunka and Vitouch, 1999; Barling et al., 2003;
Thomas et al., 2004; Sageer et al., 2012). Additionally, research has also indicated that by altering various
aspects of the work environment, an organization may provide its employees with higher levels of
motivation and satisfaction, which ultimately will lead to increased worker productivity (Thomas et al.,
2004). Notwithstanding, to correctly manipulate these job-related variables, an organization first needs to
identify and quantify its employees’ motivation and satisfaction levels. Quantifying the factors regarding
work motivation is, arguably, not an easy task because motivation stems from both objective and
subjective elements.
Therefore, hereby we propose a new methodology to measure extrinsic motivation in which the
influence of job satisfaction is remarkable. It is so because motivation is operationalized, among other
factors, in terms of questions about satisfaction
5
. The questionnaires should cover the four aspects
regarding extrinsic motivation and shown in Figure 1. In the analysis further developed here, surveys are
designed for Faculty members and accordingly so are the questions. The questions are no explicitly
arranged in four blocks: regulation, self-development, environment, and awareness
6
. This is the
recommended procedure for researchers or HR managers who try to apply the use of EMI. However, we
kindly request that you note that the enclosed survey is far from being an example, as it is designed
specifically for Faculty members. And questionnaires should always fit to the special circumstances and
characteristics of the job analyzed occupation.
5 Find all the questions in the survey, which is detailed in the Appendix.
6 Questions are intended to gather information from a large number of factors, including working conditions, salary,
promotions, autonomy, and role conflict.
Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management / Business-and-Management.org
6
Figure 1: Key Factors for Developing a Motivation Questionnaire.
COEFFICIENT OF WORKING CONDITIONS
The EMI is built upon the following assumptions: i) organizations are complex, dynamic
environments in which the workforce can be managed and it is used to meet goals; ii) changes in the
productivity of an organization can occur by increases/decreases in total motivation; iii) a greater
extrinsic motivation, ceteris paribus, involves a greater degree of total motivation and, therefore, a higher
productivity level; and iv) the occupational risk involved in each occupation is implicit in the wage:
higher risk leads to higher wages because a risk premium must be paid.
In the literature review, extrinsic motivation (EM) is regarded to be affected by several kinds of
rewards. We simplify the analysis by classifying all extrinsic rewards into three groups: gross income,
working hours, and the coefficient of working conditions. The gross income variable entails all monetary
rewards. The working hours inform of the number of hours spent at the workplace. Finally, the coefficient
of working conditions reports the satisfaction level with the environment and the personal fulfillment.
While gross income and working hours can be quantified objectively because of their quantitative nature,
the coefficient of working conditions is more of a qualitative nature and, hence, presents more difficulties.
The coefficient or working conditions is constructed through a Likert scale and later standardized to
1. Respondents were asked to respond to items by indicating their level of agreement using a five-point
Likert scale, in which 1 is identified with the lowest level of satisfaction and 5 with the highest degree of
satisfaction. A five-point Likert scale is used for several reasons. First, the odd number of choices
includes an indifference point; that is, without strong preference in either direction. Second, too many
points do not necessarily add any value or increase the validity of the findings. In fact, Miller’s law
(1956) indicates that the number of objects an average human can hold in working memory is 7 ± 2. In
addition, Dawes’ (2008) analysis observes no significant differences in variances when comparing the 5-
point to the 7-point Likert scale.
Under the theoretical assumptions already discussed, it seems clear that the extrinsic motivation of a
worker will be greater as a result of: i) a higher income; ii) less working hours; and iii) a higher
coefficient of working conditions. Therefore, the equation to assess the extrinsic motivation of a worker
"i" is given by



(1)
Where

is the real income of a worker i in annual terms,
stands for the number of working
hours per year, and
is the standardized coefficient of working conditions or satisfaction level of
employee i, calculated as the mean of the scores given by the worker for each survey question. The
standardization of this coefficient leads to
. Further simplifying, the EMI can be expressed as

 
(2)
Where
is the real income per hour worked, and
the already familiar, standardized coefficient
of the working conditions. Therefore, the extrinsic motivation of a worker at a given time t we thought
about time as being indexed by t where t is valued by whole members (t = 0, 1, 2,…,n) depends on the
hourly-earned wage and the level of satisfaction with the working conditions. In this framework, EMI
will peak when the worker is completely satisfied (5 to answer any and all of the raised issues) given a
Extrinsic Motivation
Regulation
Self-Development
Awareness
Environment in
the workplace
Reward/
Punishment
Relationship with
the boss
Autonomy
Ego
Search for approval
Chance of
Promotion
Conscious
recension
Congruence
Means available
Relationship with
fellows
Training offered
Rhythms, pauses…
To be determined
in future research
Berumen Sergio A., Pérez-Megino Luis P. and Arriaza Ibarra Karen
7
fixed income, and it is worth zero when the worker is completely dissatisfied (1 to answer any and all of
the issues raised).
The EMI can also be estimated for a group S, in this case S representing a company, a region, or a
particular profession. Re-writing equation (2) in terms of group S

 
(3)
Where
is a weighted-average of the real income per hour worked in S, and
is the standardized
level of satisfaction in S, so that
.
We expect the EMI to fluctuate over time between and within groups. This could be either the result
from changes in job-related variables or simply because no changes occur at all, i.e. the real wage will
decrease with inflation. We may calculate the corresponding variations between periods by comparing the
respective EMIs over time with a simple index number. Thus, the relative change in the EMI of a group S
between period t, and period t-1 is





(4)
Thus, a score of 1 would indicate that the EM of the group has remained constant over time, while
an index greater than 1 means that the EM of the group has increased. By the same token, a ratio below 1
would report a bad performance. It is also possible to calculate the differences in EM between groups, Z
and S, in period t. The procedure is the same than in (4) but comparing groups instead of periods of time.
Hence, we proceed as follows:


(5)
In both cases, the change in the EMI is simply calculated by subtracting 1 from the index, and
obtaining the rate of change, which is generally expressed in percentage.
Additionally, by using a complex index of aggregative type, the EMI of organizations, where
different groups (e.g. departments, sections…) may coexist, and it could be calculated as a whole. By
doing so, it is also possible to provide comparisons of the EMI, for instance, by occupations, companies,
organizational departments, or even countries:









(6)
Where Z and S are two different groups, 

and 

are the extrinsic motivation indexes for
each group, and
is the weight of each subgroup i within the relative group Z or S depending on its
belongingness.
The EMI will report on changes that occur in the EM of workers from the selected group unit. We
could also suggest complementary formulations, based on the methodology of the consumer price index
(CPI), using Laspeyres or Paasche indexes (Turvey, 2004). Then extrinsic motivation could be measured
by a wage index (per hours worked), weighted by the standardized coefficient of working conditions:







(7)
The Paasche index is obtained when this ratio is assessed in the current period t. Thus, by setting 0
as base period, a Laspeyres index is obtained. It is reasonable to adopt Paasche instead of Laspeyres index
since the working conditions change over short periods of time. A wage index based on Laspeyres index
would be obsolete in periods greater than one-year time.
An additional complication comes when there is the intention to compare workers whose wages are
expressed in different currencies or simply when workers live in regions/countries where prices are
different. In such cases, the EMI needs to be homogenized. By computing purchasing power parity (PPP)
in the index, we do not only mitigate the effect of receiving wages in different currencies but also adjust
for different price levels
7
. Therefore, the optimal EMI index for comparison between two groups, when
observing monetary differences, can be written as
7 Now, it is possible to make comparisons between organizational units from all over the world.
Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management / Business-and-Management.org
8






(8)
Where 
and 
indicate the purchasing power parity for group S and Z respectively.
3.1 Application of the EMI to Faculty Members
In order to prove the utility of the index, we do apply the EMI to university Faculty members
8
. We
collected representative samples, according to the size of the universities at hand, and also their location:
Germany (Freie Universität and Humboldt Universität zu Berlin) and Spain (Universidad Rey Juan
Carlos). Surveys were solely handed out to Faculty members from humanities and social sciences’
faculties and, more specifically, to those teaching in the fields of Business Administration and
Economics. The analysis was conducted in 2013, the number of respondents was, in total, 196 (118 for
Spanish Universidad Rey Juan Carlos, 52 for Humboldt Universität, and 26 for Freie Universität), and
respondents were approached either in their offices (Spain) or in the department’s meetings (Germany).
Table 2 shows the mean values obtained in the surveys.
Table 2: Mean Value of each Question of the Survey
Question
URJC (Vicálvaro)
Humboldt Universität
Freie Universität
1
3,7000
4,4651
4,6471
2
3,5500
4,0000
4,7059
3
3,3700
4,2326
4,6471
4
2,6300
4,0930
4,0588
5
2,8800
3,7674
4,0588
6
2,1000
3,7907
4,4706
7
1,9800
4,3023
4,1765
8
2,0000
2,8140
3,0000
9
3,0200
4,4186
4,7059
10
2,5800
4,2326
4,8824
11
3,6800
4,5581
4,7647
12
2,6200
1,6279
1,6471
13
3,4500
1,6512
1,4118
14
3,0200
4,4884
4,8235
15
2,1500
4,3721
4,1176
n
100
43
17
N
118
52
26
Notes: Mean values are expressed in scale 1-5, as indicated in the questionnaire. Please see Annex I, where the
polls for universities are specified.
Table 3 refers to the fundamental variables for estimating the EMI. Professorship categories are
expressed in terms of government recognition, according to their home country. Therefore, the groups are
not entirely homogeneous but still show many similarities. In relation to job security, the Spanish teachers
overwhelmingly belong to the category of civil servants while the same cannot be affirmed for their
German counterparts. In the case of Germany, the teacher’s gross income (W level) appears in the
Bundesbesolgunsordnung (BBesO) or federal wage scale. On this scale we find W1 Privatdozent
(Lecturer) those who have a PhD but still cannot supervise PhD students, W2 Extraordinarius
(Associate) they have some influence but their careers are still in process of consolidation, and finally
W3 Ordinarius (Professor) those in charge of research groups, with established careers and permanent
Faculty positions
9
. In Spain, professorship and lecturer groups are divided into more than three
categories. In order to establish comparisons, we selected those with the most similarities to the German
system: Contratado Doctor (Lecturer) has a PhD and is accredited by ANECA or ACAP, Profesor
Titular (Associate Professor) has a PhD and is accredited by ANECA; he has also won, through
8 
the crises, wages were greatly lowered, and most of the monetary bonuses suppressed.
9 For more information about academic career structure in Germany, see Research and Academic Jobs in Germany.
Link: http://www.careeredu.eu/index.php?doc=1
Berumen Sergio A., Pérez-Megino Luis P. and Arriaza Ibarra Karen
9
competition, a civil servant position, and finally Catedrático (Full Professor) have a PhD and is
accredited by ANECA
10
.
Table 3: Variables needed for 
calculus, 2013
University
Teacher Categories
Deflated gross
income (annual)
Working hours per
year
Coefficient of
working conditions,
URJC (Vicálvaro)
Catedrático
39.590,46€
2016
0,4656
Profesor titular
31.469,45€
Contratado Doctor
26.976,54€
Freie Universität
W3 Ordinarius
91.323,16€
2024
0,8778
W2 Extraordinarius
64.184,61€
W1 Privatdozent
49.744,80€
Humboldt Universität
zu Berlin
W3 Ordinarius
91.323,16€
2024
0,8090
W2 Extraordinarius
64.184,61€
W1 Privatdozent
49.744,80€
Notes: To calculate deflated gross income we assess the following information for Spain: base salary, extra and
special allowance, adjusted to an annual inflation rate of 0.2%. Ons old, teaching, and research supplements are
excluded. In 2013, we found 14 payments, including summer and Christmas payments, whose amounts differ from
the ordinary wage. For Germany: the annual inflation rate is 1.3%. Supplements were excluded from marital union,
child and the amount linked to the performance of W1 and W2, which varies depending on the quantity and quality of
publications and teaching. The number of pays is 14, including summer and Christmas payments.
Business days are calculated by country, depending on holidays and weekends. Hours worked are taken daily as
listed in the full-time contract, 8 hours.
Working conditions
were calculated as the mean of all questions, excluding the eighth and twelfth. For calculation
purposes the question number thirteen had to be reversed, taking the opposite mean.
Source: Tabla de Retribuciones PDI 2013 (Spain) and forschung.w-besoldung.net (Germany) for nominal wages, Statistisches
Budensant (Germany, November 2013) and Instituto Nadiconal de Estadísitica (Spain, November 2013) for inflation, and
www.días-laborales.es
(Spain) and
www.arbeitstage.de
(Germany) for working hours.
We consider gross income for analysis because tax provisions differ among countries, both for VAT
and for income tax. The latter varies depending on marital status, number of household members and
personal aspects. It is also usual to find different individual income tax rates among countries. On the
other hand, only common monetary rewards among groups are considered, i.e. supplements such as
seniority, research and teaching were excluded.
3.2 Main Findings
The results are shown in Table 4. Whilst 
is valid for comparison between groups of the same
country (Germany), it needs to be homogenized through PPP when intending to compare all faculty
members.
Table 4: 
and homogenized 
by university, 2013
University
Teacher categories

PPP
(2013)


URJC (Vicálvaro)
Catedrático
9,1435
0,680
13,4463
Profesor Titular
7,2679
10,6880
Contratado Doctor
6,2303
9,1622
Freie Universität
W3 Ordinarius
39,6065
0,781
51,7126
W2 Extraordinarius
27,8366
35,6423
W1 Privatdozent
21,5741
27,6237
Humboldt Universität zu
Berlin
W3 Ordinarius
36,5022
0,781
46,7378
W2 Extraordinarius
25,6548
32,8487
W1 Privatdozent
19,8832
25,4586
Figure 2 shows the results by category of teacher and university. It is clear the existing disparity
between German and Spanish university teachers.
10  was used.
So, most jobs are governed by the old system.
Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management / Business-and-Management.org
10
Figure 2: Homogenized EMi by university, 2013
We apply the proposed index,
, to compare extrinsic motivation between two groups at a time t,
obtaining the following results for German universities
11
(Table 5). The results presented for
and
would be exactly the same if the three variables of the index concur. In this case, working hours and gross
income for each category are the same because both groups belong to the same region and, thus, are
affected by the same regulations. The coefficient of working conditions
is the only variable which
differs. As
has the same value for the three subgroups, the result is symmetrical.
Table 5: Comparison between Freie and Humboldt, 2013
University
Teacher Categories

Freie Universität (z)
W3 Ordinarius
39,6065
1,0850
-
W2 Extraordinarius
27,8366
1,0850
-
W1 Privatdozent
21,5741
1,0850
-
Humboldt Universität
zu Berlin (s)
W3 Ordinarius
36,5022
-
0,9216
W2 Extraordinarius
25,6548
-
0,9216
W1 Privatdozent
19,8832
-
0,9216
Notes: Purchasing Power Parities for GDP: National currency units per US dollars, OECD Database (2014)
Table 6 compares Universidad Rey Juan Carlos (Vicálvaro Campus, Madrid) with Freie Universität
(Berlin). To the extent that both belong to different countries, it is necessary to use homogenized EMI.
Table 6: Comparison between URJC and Freie, 2013
University
Teacher Categories
Homogenized

Universidad Rey Juan
Carlos (z)
Catedrático
13,4463
0,2600
-
Profesor Titular
10,6880
0,2999
-
Contratado Doctor
9,1622
0,3318
-
Freie Universität (s)
W3 Ordinarius
51,7126
-
3,8459
W2 Extraordinarius
35,6423
-
3,3348
W1 Privatdozent
27,6237
-
3,0150
11 Recall that there is no need to use PPPs when comparing similar groups: same country, same region.
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
Catedrático
Profesor Titular
Contratado Doctor
W3 Ordinarius
W2 Extraordinarius
W1 Privatdozent
W3 Ordinarius
W2 Extraordinarius
W1 Privatdozent
URJC (Vicálvaro)
Freie Universität
Humboldt Universität
Berumen Sergio A., Pérez-Megino Luis P. and Arriaza Ibarra Karen
11
The great disparity observed between Spanish and German universities is mainly explained by
significant differences in the standardized coefficient of working conditions,
, and real annual wages.
Calculations of homogenized EMI place URJC faculty members well below those from Freie Universität,
as it may be seen when looking at
. Figure 3 shows the mean of homogenized EMI by university,
reflecting the disparity between German and Spanish Faculty members. There is also divergence between
German groups, which is entirely explained by the inferior working conditions at Humbold Universität.
Figure 2: Homogenized EMi (mean) across universities, 2013
Notes: URJC (Black), Freie Universität (Dark Gray) and Humboldt Universität zu Berlin (Light Gray)
3. 3 Simulation Experiments
In the previous analysis the EMI was applied with research objectives, i.e. to have a better
understanding of the job satisfaction among European scholars. However, the possibilities that the EMI
brings along are much relevant than that, especially for decision-making. In fact, the EMI turns out to be
a tool of the utmost importance for the private sector. As it is shown when running different simulations,
the HR departments are provided with a valuable tool. HR managers are able now to improve their
understanding about the reasons behind turnover and, most importantly, they get to know what strategies
would allow the organization to attract and retain valuable employees. In addition, the most relevant
feature of the EMI is that it allows the organization to measure the consequences of its actions and, hence,
to be able to reduce existing gaps in job satisfaction.
To illustrate this, two different firms from the same sector (business consultancy) are analyzed. To
ease things up, it is assumed that both companies are located in the same country (United States). Thus,
there is no need to adjust the EMI through PPP. Four different scenarios are proposed, trying to cover
some of the most-likely situations that can be found in the private sector. All variables are set as it is more
convenient for analysis purposes. In all fictitious scenarios, however, variable values are meant to match
real-life situations.
1
st
SCENARIO: The Importance of the Salary
As shown in Table 7, when the coefficient of working conditions and working hours are practically
the same, the element that becomes a real difference is the annual income. In the first scenario, Firm Y
pays around 10,000 USD more than Firm X, and that places employees of Firm Y with a higher EMI.
Accordingly, we expect employees of Firm Y to be more committed to the firm than employees of Firm
X, basically because: i) employees of Firm Y tend to value positively their firm when compared with their
competitors (Firm X); and ii) the extrinsic rewards provided by Firm Y are significantly higher, which
make employees to be more involved and motivated. Finally, we can expect employees of Firm X to
move to Firm Y when job offers are available, which would raise turnover costs for Firm X.
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management / Business-and-Management.org
12
Table 7 (1
st
Scenario): Consu
Firm
Categories
Deflated gross
income (annual)
Working hours
per year
Coefficient of
working
conditions,
EMI
X
Senior Manager
100,000 USD
2024
0,63
31.13
Senior Consultant
80,000 USD
24.90
Junior Consultant
60,000 USD
18.68
Y
Senior Manager
110,000 USD
2024
0,66
35.86
Senior Consultant
90,000 USD
29.35
Junior Consultant
70,000 USD
22.83
2
nd
SCENARIO: When Working Conditions Is All that Matters
In the second scenario we propose one of the more realistic examples that can be found in the private
sector: there are no huge difference in the salary nor in the working hours, although the working
conditions differ greatly. In this case, the variations in the EMI are even greater than in the first scenario,
given that the working conditions are significantly inferior in Firm Y. Hence, Firm X employees are more
motivated and committed than Firm Y employees. We do expect here employees of Firm Y to move to
Firm X when job offers are made. Thus, turnover costs are expected to rise for Firm Y.
Table 8 (2
nd

Firm
Categories
Deflated gross
income (annual)
Working hours
per year
Coefficient of
working
conditions,
EMI
X
Senior Manager
100,000 USD
2024
0,85
42.00
Senior Consultant
80,000 USD
33.60
Junior Consultant
60,000 USD
25.20
Y
Senior Manager
103,000 USD
2024
0,65
33.08
Senior Consultant
82,000 USD
26.33
Junior Consultant
61,000 USD
19.60
3
rd
SCENARIO: Working Hours Do Differ Among Firms
The only difference here lies in the working hours: whereas Firm X employees work 2024
hours/year, employees in Firm Y do work 2277 hours/year. In simple words, employees of Firm Y work
one extra hour per day, or 257 hours more per year. When working hours are higher in one firm, ceteris
paribus, we find higher EMI values for the firm with less working hours, because it provides better
conditions to its employees. Thus, we can expect employees of Firm Y to move to Firm X when job
offers are made. And thus, turnover costs will tend to increase for Firm Y.
Table 9 (3
rd

Firm
Categories
Deflated gross
income (annual)
Working hours
per year
Coefficient of
working
conditions,
EMI
X
Senior Manager
100,000 USD
2024
0,70
34.60
Senior Consultant
80,000 USD
27.67
Junior Consultant
60,000 USD
20.75
Y
Senior Manager
100,000 USD
2277
0,70
30.75
Senior Consultant
80,000 USD
24.60
Junior Consultant
60,000 USD
18.45
4
th
SCENARIO: The Most Plausible Scenario
The 4
th
scenario is, without any doubt, the most likely to find in all markets and sectors. Whilst one
firm may pay higher wages than the other, the coefficient of working conditions is greater in the firm with
lower wages. Unsurprisingly, these effects could even cancel out. In the present scenario, both firms work
the same number of hours per year. However, the coefficient of working conditions is higher for firm Y,
and wages are higher in Firm X. Additionally, there are no significant differences between firms neither
in working conditions for their employees nor in their wages. The result is that the EMI is about the same
in the two firms. Therefore, job changes are not expected when job offers are made, except in very special
cases where the employees might feel isolated or unsatisfied. In the 4
th
scenario, turnover costs are
expected to increase for now firm.
Berumen Sergio A., Pérez-Megino Luis P. and Arriaza Ibarra Karen
13
Table 10 (4
th

Firm
Categories
Deflated gross
income (annual)
Working hours
per year
Coefficient of
working
conditions,
EMI
X
Senior Manager
110,000 USD
2024
0,65
35.33
Senior Consultant
87,000 USD
27.94
Junior Consultant
65,000 USD
20.87
Y
Senior Manager
100,000 USD
2024
0,70
34.58
Senior Consultant
80,000 USD
27.67
Junior Consultant
60,000 USD
20.75
3. 4 Utility of the EMI
We conceive the EMI as a valuable managerial tool for researchers, public institutions, and private
businesses. The EMI is an attempt to reconcile research in HR with practice, i.e. too often research
studies are irrelevant for HR managers or chief executives. In this sense, the EMI aims to fill the lacunae
by providing relevant information to both researchers and employers. On one hand, researchers are now
able to dig in deeper in the state of affairs of any occupation, i.e. they can collect and process the data in
order to obtain useful information about the rationale of a job. On the other hand, HR departments are
able to: i) track the satisfaction level among employees; ii) perceive the effects of their labor policies on
job satisfaction and commitment; iii) reduce turnover costs by retaining quality employees; and iv) to
attract new talent by spotting and erasing the weaknesses of the organization with respect to the
competitors.
In both cases, the information that the EMI can provide is highly valuable. For instance, in the case
of academic research, one might be interested in knowing why some people work under really
unfavorable conditions, or why some employers offer disproportionately negative working conditions. On
the other hand, and where the EMI is more likely to be applied, HR departments may use this tool to
attract and retain talent and to reduce turnover costs. All in all, the EMI has the ability to measure how a
particular policy or strategy affects upon an employee’s motivation and satisfaction level, and what the
overall effect of such alteration is. In other words, it provides remarkable information for an organization
decision-making process.
Regarding the utility of the EMI in the examples above, we can conclude that in the case of a
researcher, the EMI facilitates the way in which information is interpreted. This is obvious when
analyzing divergences for Faculty members with respect to their university membership. In such case, as
researchers we seek to understand why job satisfaction is markedly different from those scholars teaching
in Germany than for those in Spain, but we do not try to change the course of events. However, the EMI
becomes much more valuable for the Human Resources Department in its strategic function when the
simulation experiments are run. Here, the EMI does not only provide a deeper understanding of the facts,
but it also identifies potential consequences of policy decision-making. In the First Scenario, higher
wages, other things being equal, mean that a firm can retain quality employees and attract bright
employees from other firms if job offers are made. Accordingly, turnover costs will increase for the other
firms, whilst productivity is expected to be higher in this firm paying higher wages. In the Second
Scenario, there are only significant differences in the working conditions. An organization with better
working conditions has more committed and motivated employees than other firms. Thus, turnover costs
are lower for this firm, and productivity probably higher. In this hypothetic case, this firm also has the
ability to attract talented employees. Lastly, in the Fourth and most plausible scenario, some firms may
pay higher wages than others, although firms with lower wages offer superior working conditions. In this
case, it is likely that these differences cancel out overall, i.e. some employees emphasize the monetary
rewards while others care more about self-enhancement, integration, group dynamics, close relationship
to the bosses, etc. Has the EMI any utility in such a case? It certainly does. An organization can, taking
into account its capacity and level of resources, address monetary differences or specific differences in
working conditions in order to enlarge the gap with existing firms. Thus, it is in these scenarios that HR
departments should use the EMI to promote job satisfaction, increase commitment and productivity
levels, and also to attract talent and reduce turnover costs. Combining both survey data and the EMI, an
organization easily gets to know what needs to be enhanced and to which extent.
Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management / Business-and-Management.org
14
4 CONCLUSION AND DISCUSSION
Although the initial objective of the research, which was to provide a tool of practical significance
for both researchers and HR managers, has been fulfilled, we must recognize some limitations of the
index presented here. First, the need for cooperation with employers when the investigation is carried out
by external sources and the gross annual income is not known. Second, the EMI does not consider net
annual income, which implies that the positive or negative impact of fiscal pressure exerted in the country
is not measured. This methodological difficulty is due to tax provisions, which differ by individual. If the
fiscal pressure is to be measured, the anonymity of the survey will be lost and, thus, questionnaire
answers would be, most likely, biased for fear of job loss and reprimands. Third, the EMI fluctuates
freely without bound. In other words, it cannot reach a peak. This is the most severe difficulty of the
index, given it increases asymptotically if so does income. Accordingly, when annual income attains a
considerable amount of money, the relevance of the EMI is certainly distorted. Finally, all variables of the
EMI vary over short periods of time and, therefore, annual monitoring is highly recommended for those
aiming to follow the evolution of a group over time. All in all, we expect to have satisfactorily answered
the criticism coming from Hambrick (2007), Rousseau (2007), DeNisi et al. (2014), and especially the
call for empirical tools made by Saari and Judge (2004).
In a world where globalization has highly altered the way of doing things, competition has increased
vastly and, as a consequence, most business practices need to be optimized. The struggle for one of the
most critical resources, human resources, can provide organizations with competitive advantages that
might lead to dominate the market. The importance of human capital was already seen in the past when
most firms established HR departments in the 1960s, and the role of HRM within the firm has been
growing ever since. Today’s agreement upon HR departments is clear: it bears a strategic function that
looks for the best performance and coordination of all resources. The last decades have led to an evident
conclusion that makes room for empirical tools such as the EMI: motivations are changing radically, and
it is necessary to consider them as one of the main instruments for stimulating the human resources to get
the best results. Although it is true that HR departments have its own tools to promote job satisfaction as
well as to attract and retain talent, it is less clear whether they have a tool such as the EMI. The strength
of the EMI is that it does not only provide a deep and insightful overview of the market, but also allows
comparisons with the competitors. The EMI has proven indeed to be very useful: i) to quantify any
worker’s EM level; ii) to analyze, through historical series, the evolution of a group in the period
 
;
iii) to compare the motivation of a group (e.g. university faculty member) between countries in period t;
iv) to identify the focus of dissatisfaction; and v) to decision-making procedures, e.g. by a better
managing of turnover costs.
In fact, the EMI allows economic agents to assess the impact of remuneration as well as the effect of
strategies regarding working-time and working-conditions. We hereby present a powerful tool for HRM
that is closely related to productivity levels and turnover costs. The EMI is ultimately designed to serve as
a tool for attracting and retaining talent. The inner workings of the EMI must be understood in the context
of a social responsible organization with a win-win tool at its disposal. By assuring job satisfaction not
only is the organization better off because its productivity tends to increase, but also the employees enjoy
greater harmony and happiness. This is because the greater the satisfaction, the higher the motivation
levels and the willingness of workers to produce.
The methodological limitations of our own research point the way for future research, where
opportunities are abundant, especially in the field of developing empirical tools of higher quality. Yet
there are still several questions that need to be answered in regard extrinsic motivation, and intrinsic
motivation: Is it possible to measure somehow intrinsic motivation? If so, could an index of total
motivation be constructed? How should such an index weight the relative importance of extrinsic and
intrinsic motivation?
REFERENCES
Adams, J.S. (1965). Inequity in Social Exchange. In L. Berkowitz (Ed.), Advances in Experimental and
Social Psychology (pp. 276-299). New York, NY: Academic Press.
Alderfer C.P. (1969). An Empirical Test of New Theory of Human Need. Organizational Behavior &
Human Performance, 4(1), 142175.
Aziri, B. (2011). Job Satisfaction: A Literature Review. Management Research and Practice, 3(4), 77-86.
Bandura, A. (1977). Self-efficacy: Toward a Unifying Theory of Behavioral Change. Psychological
Review, 84, 191-215.
Berling, J., Hurrell, J., Braverman, M., Collins, R., Gelles, M., Scrivner, W., and Keita, J. (2003).
Terrorized Workers: Employee Well-being Following 9/11. Unpublished manuscript.
Berumen Sergio A., Pérez-Megino Luis P. and Arriaza Ibarra Karen
15
Berlyne, D. E. (1960). Conflict, Arousal and Curiosity. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Bruni, L. & Porta, P. L. (2006). Economics of Happines: Framing the Analysis. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Caplan, R.D. (1987). Person-Environment Fit Theory and Organizations: Commensurate Dimensions,
Time Perspectives, and Mechanisms. Journal of Vocational Behavior, 31, 248-267.
Chen, Y., Gupta, A. & Hoshower, L. (2006). Factors that motivate business faculty to conduct research:
An expectancy theory analysis. Journal of Education for Business, 81, 179-189.
Colesca, S. (2010). Online Consumer: Theories of Human Relativism. Anfiteatru Economic, 12 (28), 694-
699.
Csikszentmihalyi, M. (1990). Flow: The Psychology of Optimal Experience. New York: Harper & Row.
Davis, K. (1957). Human Relations in Business. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Dawes, J. (2008). Do Data Characteristics Change According to the Number of Scale Points Used?
International Journal of Market Research, 50(1), 61-77
Deci, E. L. & Ryan, R. M. (1985). Intrinsic Motivation and Self Determination in Human Behavior. New
York: Plenum Press.
Deci, E. L. & Ryan, R. M. (2000). The “What” and the “Why” of Goal Pursuits: Human Needs and the
Self-Determination of Behavior. Psychological Inquiry, 11(4), 227-268.
Denisi, A. S., Wilson, M. S. & Biteman, J. (2014). Research and Practice in HRM: A Historical
Perspective. Human Resource Management Review, 24(3), 219-231.
Dulebohn, J. H., Ferris, G. R. & Stodd, J. T. (1995). The History and Evolution of Human Resource
Management. In G. F., Sherman, D. Rosen & D. T. Barnum (Eds.). Handbook of Human Resource
Management. New Jersey: John Wiley.
Elliot, A. J. (1999). Approach and Avoidance Motivation and Achievement Goals. Educational
Psychologist, 34(3), 169-189.
English, H. B. (1921). Dynamic Psychology and the Problem of Motivation. Psychological Review,
28(4), 239-248.
Ford, M. E. (1992). Motivating Humans. Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Griffin, R. W. and Moorhead, Gregory (2014). Organizational Behavior: Managing People and
Organizations. Cengage Learning, 2
nd
edition.
Hackman, J. R., and Oldham, G. R. (1976). Motivation through the design of work: Test of a theory.
Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 16, 250-279.
Hambrick, D. C. (2007). The Field of Management’s Devotion to Theory: Too Much of a Good Thing?.
Academy of Management Journal, 50(6), 1020-1026.
Herzberg, F. (1957). The Motivation to Work. 2
nd
Edition. John Wiley.
Herzberg, F. (1968). One more time: How do you motivate employees? Harvard Business Review, pp.
52-62.
Kahya, E. (2008). The Effects of Job Performance on Effectiveness. International Journal of Industrial
Ergonomics, 39(1), 96-104.
Kochan, T. A., Katz, H. C. & McKersie, R. B. (1986). The Transformation of American Industrial
Relations. New York: Basic Books.
Korunka, C., and Vitouch, O. (1999). Effects of the Implementation of Information Technology on
Employee’s Strain and Job Satisfaction: A Context-Dependent Approach. Work and Stress, 34, 341-
363.
Landy, F. J. (1978). An Opponent Process Theory of Job Satisfaction. Journal of Applied Psychology,
63(5), 533-547.
Landy, F. J. & Becker, W. S. (1987). Work Motivation Reconsidered. In L. L. Cummings & B. M. Staw
(Eds.). Research in Organizational Behavior, 9: 1-38. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Lathman, G.P., and Pinder, C.C. (2005). Work Motivation Theory and Research at the Dawn of the
Twenty-first Century. Annual Review of Psychology, 56, 495-516.
Locke, E.A. (1969). What is job satisfaction? Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 4, 309-
336.
Locke, E.A. (1976). The nature and causes of job satisfaction: Handbook of Industrial and
Organizational Psychology. Chicago: Rand McNally.
Int. Journal of Business Science and Applied Management / Business-and-Management.org
16
Mahoney, T. A. (1988). Productivity defined: The relativity of efficiency, effectiveness, and change. In J.
P. Campbell & R. J. Campbell (Eds.). Productivity in Organizations: New Perspectives from
Industrial and Organizational Psychology. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Maslow, A. H. (1943). A Theory of Human Motivation. Psychological Review, 50, 370-396.
McClelland, D.C. (1988). Human Motivation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Miller, G.A. (1956). The Magical Number Seven, Plus or Minus Two: Some Limits on Our Capacity for
Processing Information. Psychological Review, 63(2), 81-97.
Miller, N. E. (1944). Personality and the Behavior Disorders. In J. McVicker Hunt (Ed.). Experimental
Studies in Conflict, 431-465. New York: Ronald.
Munir, A. (2011). Motivation of Employees through Performance Appraisal: Factors of Employee
Motivation. London, UK: Lambert Publishing.
Perrin, F. A. C. (1923). The Psychology of Motivation. Psychological Review, 30(3), 176-191.
Pinder, C.C. (1984). Work Motivation: Theory, Issues, and Applications. Glenview, IL.: Scott Foresman.
Pinder, C.C. (2008). Work Motivation in Organizational Behavior. Psychology Press: Taylor & Francis
Group.
Porter, L.W. and Lawler, E.E. (1968). Managerial Attitudes and Performance. Homewood, IL: Dorsey
Press and Richard D. Irwin.
Rousseau, D. M. (2007). A Sticky, Leveraging, and Scalable Strategy for High-Quality Connections
Between Organizational Practice and Science. Academy of Management Journal, 50(5), 1037-1042.
Saager, A. Rafat, S., and Agarwal, P. (2012). Identification of Variables Affecting Employee Satisfaction
and Their Impact on the Organization. Journal of Business and Management, 5(1), 32-39.
Saari, L.M., and Judge, T.A. (2004). Employee Attitudes and Job Satisfaction. Human Resources
Management, 43(4), 395-407.
Seneca, L. A. (2014). Hardship and Happiness. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Silverthorne, C. (2004). The Impact of Organizational Culture and Person-Organization Fit on
Organizational Commitment and Job Satisfaction in Taiwan. Leadership & Organization
Development Journal, 25(7), 592-599.
Spector, P. E. (1997). Job Satisfaction: Application, Assessment, Cause and Consequences. Thousand
Oaks, CA: Sage Publications, Inc.
Thomas, A., Buboltz, W.C., and Winkelspecht, C. S. (2004). Job Characteristics and Personality as
Predictors of Job Satisfaction. Organizational Analysis, 12(2), 205-219.
Turvey, R. (2004). Consumer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice. Geneve: International Labour
Organization.
Van Praag, B.M.S. & Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A. (2008). Happiness Quantified: A Satisfaction Calculus
Approach. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Vroom, V.H. (1964). Work and Motivation. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.
White, R. W. (1959). Motivation Reconsidered: The Concept of Competence. Psychological Review,
66(5), 297-333.
Wolfe, A. B. (1921). The Motivation of Radicalism. Psychological Review, 28(4), 280-300.
Yang, Jen-Te. (2010). Antecedents and Consequences of Job Satisfaction in the Hotel Industry.
International Journal of Hospitality Management, 29, 609-619.
Berumen Sergio A., Pérez-Megino Luis P. and Arriaza Ibarra Karen
17
APPENDIX
The purpose of this survey is to determine the degree of work motivation of the professors who work
in URJC, Freie and Humboldt Universities. All questions must be answered with grades 1 to 5, from
completely dissatisfied/strongly disagree (1) to completely satisfied/ completely agree (5)
1. What is the degree of satisfaction in your work as teacher?
1 2 3 4 5
2. Are you satisfied with the relationship with your closest boss?
1 2 3 4 5
3. Do you think that the work environment is proper to perform your tasks?
1 2 3 4 5
4. Do you think the University takes into account the professors’ suggestions?
1 2 3 4 5
5. Are you agree with the criteria established by the State (national or local) for the professors
promotions?
1 2 3 4 5
6. Do you think there is a correlation between the work performed and the wage perceived?
1 2 3 4 5
7. Are you satisfied with the latest reforms undertaken by the government in education issues?
1 2 3 4 5
8. Do you think the new education plan (Bologna plan) improves the quality of education?
1 2 3 4 5
9. Do you think the attitude of students motivates you to get involved in the preparation of the classes?
1 2 3 4 5
10. Do you think the University has the means (technology) needed to develop your tasks efficiently and
effectively?
1 2 3 4 5
11. Do you think that the vacation period for professors is enough?
1 2 3 4 5
12. Do you think that teaching the same subject for an extended period of time causes procrastination as
preparing classes?
1 2 3 4 5
13. Do you think that some professors are teaching more subjects than usual due to lack of staff?
1 2 3 4 5
14. Do you think it is appropriate the allocation courses system?
1 2 3 4 5
15. Are you satisfied with the time you have to devote to research activities?
1 2 3 4 5